The main goal of this study is to develop a dynamic equilibrium model of central bank swap lines that helps understand the recent observed behaviors of foreign reserves and to analyze the potential effect of the Federal Reserves’ foreign exchange swap lines on the determination of international reserves and exchange rates. The model focuses on the issue of moral hazard that can arise with the liquidity provision of the Federal Reserve through its swap lines with other central banks. This study argues that a standard debt contract under asymmetric information between lenders and borrowers may not work to model actual swap lines between the Federal Reserve and foreign central banks because lenders tend to accept credit risks in debt contract models. This study shows that debt contracts between the Federal Reserve and foreign central banks are inferior to swap contracts in the presence of the informational advantage of foreign central banks for local financial institutions in their jurisdictions. Although the proposed model is primarily intended to understand the contractual relation between the Federal Reserve and foreign central banks, it can also serve as a determination model for the nominal exchange rate. A policy implication of this model is that short-run and longrun channels are available through which the expectation formation of agents is affected by the behavior of international reserves and the credible long-term stance of the monetary policy.
The recent two decades have witnessed a relatively long trend of reserve accumulation prior to the global financial crisis and its substantial declines during the crisis in the group of emerging-market countries. Before the crisis, the academia and practical policy makers remarked that that their hoarding of international reserves might be excessive in light of the so-called “Guidotti-Greenspan” prescription for reserve adequacy. This situation held especially for reserve stocks that were more than enough to cover potential disruptions in the international settlements of imports and even in the roll-over of their short-term external debts. During the crisis, the Federal Reserve provided foreign exchange swap lines with other central banks that include the European Central Bank, the Swiss National Bank, the Bank of Japan, and the Bank of Korea.
The main goal of this study is to develop a dynamic model that helps understand the observed behaviors of foreign reserves summarized above and to analyze the potential effect of the foreign exchange swap lines of the Federal Reserves on the determination of international reserves and exchange rates. In the proposed model, foreign central banks engage in the financial intermediation between the Federal Reserve and non-U.S. financial institutions. Specifically, foreign central banks distribute U.S. dollars to local financial institutions with “variable rate” auctions while making currency swap contracts with the Federal Reserve.
A notable feature of the foreign exchange swap lines from the Federal Reserve is that different lending rates are set for different central banks, whereas the Federal Reserve does not accept credit risks that may arise from lending to local financial institutions. Given this actual working of foreign exchange swap lines, assuming that the Fed delegates its lending capacity to foreign central banks to save intermediation costs that may arise with the asymmetric information about balance sheet conditions of local financial institutions that benefited from foreign exchange swap lines may not be unreasonable. In fact, the moral hazard that can arise with the liquidity provision of the Federal Reserve through its swap lines has been considered in the academia and practical policy circles. However, a standard debt contract under asymmetric information between lenders and borrowers may not work to model actual swap lines between the Federal Reserve and foreign central banks because lenders tend to accept credit risks in debt contract models.
This study shows that debt contracts between the Federal Reserve and foreign central banks are inferior to swap contracts between them in the presence of the informational advantage of foreign central banks for local financial institutions in their jurisdictions. In the presence of a moral hazard issue, central bank swap lines may not enable a country to attain an arbitrarily large level of short-term financial debt. Therefore, seeking a prescription for an adequate financial capacity of international reserves would be desirable when the financial capacity of international reserves is defined as the sum of its international reserves and the borrowing from central bank swap lines. In this regard, if the short-term international debt is deposited in regional banks and the central bank defends the stability of regional financial markets, then the financial capacity of an international country will have the tendency to move in tandem with its broad monetary aggregates on average.
In particular, this prescription is in accordance with the view of Obstfeld, Shambaugh, and Taylor (2009 and 2010) that a central bank holds reserves as protection against “double-drain” crisis scenarios, in which banking and currency problems interact in ways that are likely to cause a sharp and disruptive external currency depreciation. The key point of their “financial stability model” is that considering the ratio of
One may also wonder if the introduction of foreign exchange swap lines can alter the way through which the exchange rate is determined in the foreign exchange market. Although the proposed model is primarily intended to understand the contractual relation between the Federal Reserve and foreign central banks, this model also describes how the nominal exchange rate is determined. In particular, the behavior of international reserves and the credible long-term stance of the monetary policy affect the expectation formation of agents through short-run and long-run channels.
The key mechanism behind this implication reflects the model feature in which a modified covered interest parity condition (up to the firstorder approximation) can be derived from the equilibrium equation for international reserves. The implications of this modified covered interest parity condition for the determination of exchange rate can be summar-ized as follows: A currency of a country is appreciated with the amount of its current and future international reserves but depreciated with its monetary aggregates when the debt capacity of international reserves is binding. This occurrence may hold even in the absence of foreign exchange swap lines.
The rest of this paper is organized as follows. The next section describes a model of central bank swap lines to mitigate U.S. dollar liquidity shocks. In Section III, I analyze the effect of central bank swap lines on the determination of nominal exchange rates and the issue of financial stability. Section IV concludes the paper.
II. A Model of Central Bank Swap Lines
In this section, I present a model of central bank foreign exchange swap lines. This model has four players: the Federal Reserve, foreign central banks, local wholesale financial institutions, and retail private banks. These players are all risk-neutral. Moreover, individual households are not allowed to have access to wholesale loan markets, as discussed below.
The foreign central bank holds a total stock of its international reserves at the beginning of period
The important feature of central bank swap lines is that the Federal Reserve does not bear any credit risk associated with the distribution of U.S. dollars drawn from central bank swap lines to local banks. The Federal Reserve is not a counterparty to the loan extended by the foreign central bank to the local depository institutions. Therefore, the foreign central bank bears the credit risk associated with the loans it makes to institutions in its jurisdiction.
Another important feature of central bank swap lines is the repurchased agreement between the Federal Reserve and foreign central banks. At the beginning of their transaction, the foreign central bank sells its domestic currency M t to the Federal Reserve in exchange for dollars () at a spot nominal exchange rate
The foreign central bank uses “variable-rate auctions” when providing loans with financial institutions in its jurisdiction. That is, U.S. dollar loans are allotted at the rate submitted by each successful bidder whose bid is greater than the minimum rate set by the central bank. To rationalize this assumption, the European Central Bank, the Swiss National Bank, and the Bank of England all conducted overnight variable-rate auctions for U.S. dollars during the second and third phases of foreign swap lines between the Federal Reserve and the central banks. The rate bids for dollars in these auctions tend to reflect the pressures in overseas U.S. dollar funding markets over this period.1
To rationalize the establishment of central bank swap lines, U.S. dollar liquidity shocks in local financial markets are assumed. The magnitude of U.S. dollar liquidity shocks is measured using the excess demand of U.S. dollars in each local market. A continuum of local financial markets exists where retail banks operate to help the exchange among different currencies. Each local market is differentiated ex-post depending on the realized values of U.S. dollar liquidity shocks that are idiosyncratic across different local markets. As mentioned in the introduction, addressing the issue of moral hazard in the provision of U.S. dollars through central bank swap lines is essential. The potential possibility of moral hazard problems may exist because of the asymmetric information between the Federal Reserve and local institutions. Specifically, the Federal Reserve alone does not observe these shocks unless it pays physical resources, as will be elaborated later.
I now discuss the formal description of liquidity shocks for U.S. dollars in local markets. Suppose that retail banks who operate in the local market
Local banks are also assumed to enter into forward exchange rate contracts to hedge exchange risks. The forward rate at period
Definition 2.1 (News Shocks for True Liquidity Shocks) The marketclearing condition in local market
The information structure of the model is described as follows. Determining whether the foreign central bank has certain information about the realization of U.S. dollar liquidity shocks is important when this bank enters into a contract with the Federal Reserve. This task is essential because the contractual interest rates of swap lines become the stop-out rates of auctions used to distribute U.S. dollars. Moreover, the swap agreements among central banks should be determined before auctions. In fact, if the central bank’s drawings from its swap lines are not its normal routine work, then the central bank should be able to determine in each period whether to use its swap line or not.
For this reason, “news shocks” about the realized values of marketspecific idiosyncratic liquidity shocks are assumed to exist. These “news shocks” have the same cumulative probability distribution as those of idiosyncratic shocks. The foreign central bank knows when it enters in the swap contract with the Federal Reserve and also believes that its knowledge about “news shocks” will hold true. Therefore, the foreign central bank believes that it has the full information about the realization of each local market’s risk denoted by
Definition 2.2 (Variable-Rate Auction) The foreign central bank announces a “variable-rate auction” to distribute an amount of U.S. dollars (1-
where
A wholesale bank with a market idiosyncratic shock of
Therefore, the profit of the central bank that can be obtained from the variable-rate auction is given by
Only a fraction of wholesale banks has U.S. dollar loans from the central bank’s auctions. The banks that are unsuccessful or do not participate in the central bank’s auctions do not need to make any repayments to the central bank. Therefore, the total amount of U.S. dollars distributed through this auction is (1-
Considering other ways to set the minimum rate in auctions may be possible. For example, although considering a rule to set the minimum rate that makes a zero cash flow of the central bank may be possible, this rule may not be useful to make a well-defined contract problem for central bank swap lines that address the issue of moral hazard. Therefore, I choose the rule of the minimum rate discussed earlier.
I now discuss the condition under which private debt contracts among private agents cannot replicate the foreign exchange swap lines discussed earlier if private international investors cannot verify the realized values of idiosyncratic shocks in the portfolios of private financial institutions. Considering this condition is necessary, as the debt contract developed in Bernanke, Gertler, and Gilchrist (1999) can create the same expected profit of the foreign central bank as that of a private agent who participates in the contract with its net worth .
To show this result, the debt contract between the foreign central bank and a private international investor is regarded to lead to a non-default loan rate
If the idiosyncratic shock belongs to the non-default region (
where Π() is the expected cash flow of the private international investor under the debt contract with the foreign central bank. As a result, the optimal debt contract between a private international investor and the foreign central bank can be summarized as follows:
Definition 2.3 (Debt Contract) Suppose that private international investors can borrow in the international financial market at a rate of . Under a debt contract with a private international investor, the foreign central bank solves the following optimization problem:
taking as given {(1+
In particular, the debt contract defined earlier is the one that will be available when the Federal Reserve and local wholesale banks make debt contracts without any intermediation of the foreign central bank. In this case, swap lines can proceed without any explicit role of the foreign central bank. Having debt contracts between the foreign central bank and local wholesale banks is also possible, while the foreign central bank transfers a contractual interest to the Federal Reserve. However, any of the debt contracts defined earlier cannot realize the role of variable-rate auctions in central bank swap lines. Therefore, the swap contracts discussed in this paper are differentiated from debt contracts even with the fact that the two types of contracts have an identical form of optimization problem.
In this part, I characterize the central bank liquidity swap contracts. A formal definition of a central bank currency swap contract should naturally include the following features to reflect central bank liquidity swap lines observed during the global financial crisis of 2008 to 2009:
Given this characterization of central bank swap lines, a solution to the following optimization problem can be used to satisfy the requirement for characterizing central bank swap lines.
Definition 2.4 (Central Bank Swap Contract) Assume that represents the Federal Reserve’s opportunity cost for its lending to the foreign central bank. Under a central bank currency swap contract, the foreign central bank solves the following optimization problem:
taking as given {(1+
I now discuss the reasons why such constraints should be included to define a swap problem. The requirement of
In particular, the constraint of Π()≤0 guarantees that the Federal Reserve does not participate in a debt contract (with free entries of private lenders) with the same form of objective function as that of the swap contract. This consideration is legitimate because of the asym-metric information between the Federal Reserve and the foreign central banks. In addition, given that a lower value of the constraint function leads to a higher value of the objective function but a lower value of the Federal Reserve’s revenue, assuming that a lower bound exists for the constant function that makes the Federal Reserve participate in the contract, denoted by in the definition of a central bank swap contract is reasonable. Therefore, I have rationalized the reason behind the importance of including the constraints for the central bank swap contract problem shown earlier.
Example 2.1 (Numerical Example) After describing the optimization problems of debt and swap contracts, I provide a numerical example for the model that may help to understand the important features of the model. The distribution of market-specific liquidity shocks follows a log-normal distribution: log
I now discuss the characterization of the optimal swap contract using its definition expressed earlier. Drawing the following assumption is crucial to guarantee the existence of solutions to both debt and swap contracts defined earlier.
Assumption 2.1 A unique solution to the debt contract problem with free entries of private liquidity providers is expressed as Π()=0. In this case, the contractual interest denoted by
A detailed discussion of the set of sufficient conditions confirming this assumption is provided in the Appendix.
Assumption 2.2 The value of the constraint function is denoted by
If this assumption is true, then the contractual interest under a swap contract decreases with the value of the constraint function Π(). A detailed discussion of the set of sufficient conditions confirming Assumption 2.2 is provided in the Appendix. The immediate implication of this assumption is that the highest level of the contractual interest rate can be attained with Π()=0. In this case, Assumption 2.1 guarantees that the contractual interest is greater than the opportunity cost of liquidity providers:
[TABLE 3] XPECTED PAYOFFS OF CENTRAL BANKS IN DEBT AND SWAP CONTRACTS
XPECTED PAYOFFS OF CENTRAL BANKS IN DEBT AND SWAP CONTRACTS
Proposition 2.1 Suppose that assumptions 2.1 and 2.2 are satisfied. Then, the following statements are true:
where function
A detailed discussion of formal evidence is provided in the Appendix. This proposition significantly implies that both debt and swap contracts can be characterized by the same optimization problem, whereas objective and constraint have different meanings. In particular, the reason why the optimal swap contract can guarantee a risk-less contractual interest whereas the corresponding debt contract cannot may be unknown. This result indicates that wholesale banks transfer their realized gross returns (above the contractual payment to the Federal Reserve) to the central bank under the swap contract, whereas the debt contract requires them to transfer only contractual gross returns that are below their realized ones. Note that the absence of the information asymmetry between the foreign central bank and wholesale banks can make variable-rate auctions available, while information asymmetry exists between the Federal Reserve and the foreign central bank.
Discussing the role of the spread of “covered interest parity” in this financial contract, {(1+
I now discuss the government’s budget constraint to determine how international reserves are accumulated. The government holds its dollardenominated foreign assets (denoted by ) at the beginning of each period
where is the domestic currency value of outstanding government debt at the end of period
The financial capacity of international reserves emerges in the framework discussed earlier. Specifically, international reserves act as collateral for the drawings of swap lines. Therefore, a country’s own international reserves can create a multiplier effect for the amount of U.S. dollars available to maintain the stability of domestic financial markets and the foreign exchange market. This multiplier effect is regarded as the stabilizing power of international reserves that can arise with the efficient use of central bank swap lines. The third bullet point of Proposition 2.1 is directly related to the magnitude of the international capacity of international reserves. In summary, given a level of international reserves
The most important role of central bank swap lines is to create the financial capacity of international reserves and thus help attain the stability of financial markets and the foreign exchange market. The use of central bank swap lines has a stabilizing impact on the spot nominal exchange rate at the time when it is likely to have sharp depreciations in the presence of the U.S. dollar shortage. The exchange rate effect of central bank swap lines can be summarized in the following proposition.
Proposition 2.2 Under the optimal central bank swap contract described earlier, the maximum appreciation of the spot nominal exchange rate that occurs with the introduction of central bank swap lines is determined by the leverage ratio of central bank swap lines:
where
The right-hand side of this equation (=(
The question surrounding what to do with this financial capacity of international reserves may emerge. Therefore, determining the set of desirable target variables of the financial capacity of international reserves is important.
1The variable-rate tender is defined as a tender procedure in which counterparties bid both the amount of money they want to transact with the central bank and the interest rate at which they want to enter into the transaction in the glossary of the European Central Bank. By contrast, a fixed rate tender is defined as a tender procedure in which the interest rate is specified in advance by the central bank and participating counterparties bid the amount of money they want to transact at that interest rate. 2In models with carry trades, this spread of “covered interest parity” can be interpreted as the carry trade margin earned by a currency trader who borrows U.S. dollars from the international financial market and converts them to a local currency to invest in the certificates of deposit in that country. When the spread of “covered interest parity” is high, the return to the carry trade (long position in the local currency and short in dollars) yields a high return.
III. International Reserves and Exchange Rate
The main goal of this section is to use the proposed model to analyze the potential impact of central bank swap lines on the determination of nominal exchange rates and the issue of financial stability. The immediate short-run effect of drawing the central bank swap line can be found in the forward exchange rate denoted by
In this equation, the expected appreciation rate measured by log(
Proposition 3.1 Under the optimal central bank swap contract described earlier, the expected depreciation rate is decomposed into the logarithmic difference between interest rates and the part that is affected by the ratio of the foreign central bank’s borrowing to its own international reserves:
where Δ
Figure 2 shows the prediction of the model on the effect of central bank swap lines on the expected change in the nominal exchange rate. The x-axis of this figure represents the logarithmic deviation of the ratio of the foreign central bank’s swap borrowing to its own holding of international reserves. The y-axis represents the expected depreciation rate defined as the logarithmic deviation of the ratio of forward rate to the spot exchange rate. Figure 2 shows that the magnitude of the expected appreciation increases as the ratio of drawings of swap lines to international reserves increases. Specifically, to the extent that
A policy implication of this equilibrium condition is the presence of an expectation management channel through which swap lines may have an impact on the expectation formation of participants in the forward foreign exchange market. The equilibrium equation shown earlier implies that if the expected depreciation rates (or appreciation rates) are targeted, attaining this rate through appropriate changes in the use of swap lines, to the extent that they are not excessive, will be possible. Moreover, this equation opens the possibility that the ratio of drawings of swap lines to international reserves can affect the nominal exchange rate if a channel exists through which the current forward exchange rate affects the spot exchange rate in the next period. To show the reason why this argument may be legitimate to the extent that
where lim
Note that distinguishing between short-run and long-run implications of the equilibrium condition of the model discussed earlier is necessary. The long-run implication of the model is that the current level of the nominal exchange rate is affected by the expectation on the long-term behavior of the ratio of drawings of swap lines to international reserves to the extent that the unbiasedness hypothesis of the forward exchange rate (
However, several factors should be considered to investigate whether this policy implication is true in actual cases. The effectiveness of central bank swap lines in the stability of foreign exchange markets may vary across different countries, especially their effectiveness in the stability of the exchange rate. The reason may be that drawings from central bank swap lines differ across different countries. Moreover, the size of the swap lines available varies across countries. For major industrialized countries, the capacity of central bank swap lines eventually became unlimited. The swaps used were clearly large in magnitude for many advanced countries. For every advanced country except Japan, the size of the swap has exceeded 50% of actual reserves held. In addition, in the cases of the United Kingdom, Australia, and the European Central Bank, the swap was larger than the existing reserves. For countries such as Denmark, Sweden, and New Zealand, the swap line was nearly as large as the existing reserves. The swaps to emerging countries were never larger than 50% of their actual reserves.
Moreover, the number of time periods of swap lines varies across different countries. The Federal Reserve’s liquidity swap lines took several stages before they were made available to emerging-market countries. Initially, large swap lines were offered to major industrial country central banks (European Central Bank, Bank of Japan, Bank of England, and Swiss National Bank) in 2007. In the fall of 2008, the Federal Reserve extended its swap lines to almost all advanced economies in the run-up of the global financial crisis. In the third phase of central bank liquidity swap lines starting on October 29, 2008, the Federal Reserve extended its swap lines to four emerging market countries, namely, Brazil, Korea, Mexico, and Singapore.
After identifying several factors that help create different levels of effectiveness of central bank swap lines across different countries, focusing on a particular example in which the use of central bank swap lines can be an effective tool to attain the stability of the nominal exchange rate is reasonable. One issue that emerges is whether the use of swap lines is intended to mitigate the liquidity shortage alone or to reduce the potential possibility of sharp depreciations of the nominal exchange rate. The tenors of central bank swap drawings differ across countries and also across various time periods. The European Central Bank and the Swiss National Bank chose short tenors of drawings especially when their liquidity shortage was extremely severe, and their main concern was to secure ample liquidity in interbank markets, for example, one day or within a month. I consider that the effectiveness of swap lines as a tool to affect the movements of the nominal exchange rate may require a relatively long tenor, at least enough to have a persistent impact on the expectation formation of participants in the forward foreign exchange market. The Bank of Korea’s tenors remained uniform at 84 days for drawings from its swap lines with the Federal Reserves. Therefore, regardless of the Bank of Korea’s primary purpose for the use of the its swap lines, its drawing is a good actual example to investigate.
Figure 3 demonstrates that the won-dollar exchange rate went up at the end of 2008. Although the swap line between the Bank of Korea and the Federal Reserve was set up in October 2008, the Bank of Korea’s initial drawing from its swap line with the Federal Reserve started in December 2008. For the initial two months when the Bank of Korea began to use its swap line, the Korean won depreciated as the ratio of central bank swap drawings to its own international reserves increased to its peak. After its peak, the ratio of central bank swap drawings to its own international reserves declined as the Bank of Korea began to curtail the use of its swap lines. The appreciation of the Korean won after February 2009 is more closely associated with the increases in the Bank of Korea’s own holding of international reserves, as shown in the lower left panel. Therefore, as the time span when the Bank of Korea relied on the swap line with the Federal Reserve was relatively short, its effect on the stability of foreign exchange market was also short. In summary, the plots in Figure 1 provide certain scenarios that at least open the potential possibility of the effectiveness of the Federal Reserve’s swap linein the stability of the Korean Foreign exchange market, although they are not decisive. In particular, the empirical relation between the expected depreciation rates of the Korean won (relative to the U.S. dollar) and the ratio of the Bank of Korea’s drawings to its own reserves derived in the upper right and lower left panels of Figure 3 is consistent with that of Proposition 3.1 and Figure 2.
Assumption 3.1 (Size of Capital Flights) Let
where
I now discuss the implication of this equilibrium condition for financial stability. I follow the view of Obstfeld, Shambaugh, and Taylor (2010) that the main reason for a central bank to hold foreign reserves is to protect its domestic banking sector (generally the domestic credit markets) without having limited external currency depreciation only. In particular, their “double drain” crisis scenario implies that the main concern of the central bank’s reserve management should be given to the domestic financial stability because the domestic capital flight could come with withdrawals of domestic bank deposits.
Assume that the target of the total stock of international reserves is
where is the nominal GDP measured in U.S. dollars. I now make a log-linear approximation of this equation around its steady state:
where
The log-linearized equation implies that the ratio of international reserves to the GDP increases with the ratio of
The most important feature of this rule is that the ratio of international reserves to the GDP should be proportional to the ratio of
where “control” represents the estimated effects of other variables:
As mentioned earlier, this estimation result indicates a substantial dependence of international reserves on the stock of
I now discuss the nominal exchange rate implied by the model. The equilibrium condition is a forward-looking difference equation for the nominal exchange rate. Its forward-looking solution can be written as follows:
where lim
Note that this model can be used to analyze the exchange rate effects of unconventional monetary policy measures implemented over the past several years, such as quantitative easing and forward guidance. The implied relationship between the long-term interest rates and the exchange rates of the model is identical to that implied by the conventional specification of the “uncovered interest parity” condition. Based on the recent empirical works of Chinn (2013) and Kiley (2103), the proposed model also suggests that a country’s monetary policy actions to lower long-term interest rates can contribute to a lower exchange value of its home currency.
Moreover, suppose that when the central bank expands its balance sheet, this situation leads to persistent increases in the stock of
The second implication is that the current nominal exchange rate is affected by the expected path of international reserves. In particular, the third term on the right-hand side of this equation shows that an increase in the expected path of the ratio of international reserves to the GDP increases the exchange value of the home currency. This result is caused by the spread of “covered interest parity” falling with the stock of international reserves. In particular, an increase in the stock of international reserves acts as an increase in the collateral for the borrowing from central bank swap lines. The resulting increase in the total amount of U.S. dollars available may have stabilizing effects on movements of the nominal exchange rate even during financial and currency crises.
I use the Korean quarterly data that cover 1999:3 to 2013:2 to investigate how the ratio of international reserves to the GDP or the ratio of
3In this model, the forward rate is assumed to be determined by a “nondeliverable” forward contract. The “non-deliverable” forward contract is similar to a regular forward foreign exchange contract, except that this contract does not require the physical delivery of currencies at its maturity and is typically settled in an international financial center in U.S. dollars.
In this study, I examine the implications of a dynamic equilibrium model of central bank swap lines to determine the nominal exchange rate and the role of international reserves in financial stability. The proposed model focuses on the issue of moral hazard that can arise with the liquidity provision of the Federal Reserve through its swap lines with other central banks.
This model is not only primarily intended to understand the contractual relation between the Federal Reserve and foreign central banks, but it also serves as a descriptive model to explain how the nominal exchange rate is determined. In particular, short-run and long-run channels exist through which the expectation formation of agents is affected by the behavior of international reserves and the credible long-term stance of the monetary policy.
I present a couple of issues that may be worthy of future research. First, the main concern of the model is bilateral contracts. Therefore, extending the current model to the analysis of multilateral contracts would be interesting. Second, the absence of information asymmetry between the foreign central bank and the wholesale banks in its jurisdiction makes using “variable-rate auctions” possible. In this auction, different loan rates are submitted by different wholesale banks. However, once the information problem emerges, making debt contracts between the foreign central bank and the wholesale banks is more desirable. Even with debt contracts between the foreign central bank and the wholesale banks, delivering a risk-less contractual interest payment to the Federal Reserve is still possible. Therefore, analyzing the optimal mechanism design for central bank swap lines is interesting for future research.