검색 전체 메뉴
PDF
맨 위로
OA 학술지
Executive Strength, Executive-Legislative Relations, and Budget Deficits
  • 비영리 CC BY-NC
  • 비영리 CC BY-NC
ABSTRACT
Executive Strength, Executive-Legislative Relations, and Budget Deficits
KEYWORD
budget deficits , executive strength , executive-legislative relations , parliamentary system , presidential system , conditional common pool resource theory
  • COMMON POOL RESOURCE PROBLEM OR POLICY INERTIA?

    Budget deficits arise from governments’ excessive expenditure. Early economists that examined the causes of budget deficits offer the tax-smoothing hypothesis which views the government as the “benevolent social planner” that always tries to balance the budget and predicts that deficits only arise under exceptional circumstances such as wars or recessions (Barro 1979; Lucas and Stokey 1983). However, recent studies have shown that budget deficits do happen in the absence of wars or recession and there are cross-national differences in budget deficits. Thus, many scholars have turned their attention to the effects of political factors on budget deficits. In this section, we briefly review two strands of the literature—common pool resource theory and policy inertia theory—that examine the impacts of political factors on budget deficits.

    The common pool resource theorists assume that there is a “common pool resource problem,” in which individual rationality undermines collective rationality when distributing common pool resources (Ostrom 1990). They view the budget as a common pool resource and argue that the common pool resource problem—in which politicians exploit the budget for their individual interests without considering the total tax burden—cause high budget deficit. Roubini and Sachs (1989a/1989b), for instance, argue that budget deficits are caused by multiparty governments in parliamentary systems because the coalition partners in the government tend to exploit the budget in order to deliver benefits to their constituents at the expense of a balanced budget. Thus, most of the CPR literature argues that when a central actor, who considers the total tax burden, has the power to suppress the individual politicians’ incentives to exploit the budget, deficit will decrease. Many studies have found empirical support for the CPR theory of budget deficits. For instance, Von Hagen and Hallerberg (1995) analyze the patterns of budget deficits in 12 EU member states from 1981 till 1990 and find that countries that delegate budgetary power to a strong central player show lower budget deficits because a strong central player that considers the total tax burden can solve the CPR problem. Similarly, Hallerberg and von Hagen (1999) and Hallerberg et al. (2007) examine budget deficits in 20 democracies from 1981 to 1994 and find that a centralization of power leads to a favorable condition for a lower budget deficit. Specifically, they explain that majoritarian electoral systems are more likely to produce balanced budgets because the executives are more likely to be empowered by single-party governments, in which a strong financial minister can control the budget process. However, they also explain that multiparty governments can produce balanced budgets if the financial minister is empowered to enforce the fiscal contract formed by the coalition partners. In addition, in their study of budget outcomes in Latin American countries, Hallerberg and Marier (2004) also emphasize that a weak executive increases budget deficits. They find that the executive’s strong control over the legislature effectively reduces budget deficits.

    The policy inertia theorists, on the other hand, emphasize the importance of the number of veto players who can block a change of status quo.Franzese (2002) argues that the presence of many veto players decreases the government’s ability to adjust the budget during fiscal shocks. Additionally, Tsebelis (2002) shows with spatial models that the presence of multiple veto players creates a “policy inertia” effect, which makes it harder for the government to reduce budget deficits. Many studies have found empirical support for the PI approach to budget deficits. For instance, Roubini and Sachs (1989a/1989b) find in their analysis of budget deficits in 15 Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD) countries that budget deficits tend to be higher with multiparty governments. Alt and Lowry (1994) examine the patterns of budget deficits of state governments within the United States and found that divided state governments, where the executive and the legislative branches are held by different parties, tend to be less efficient in responding to fiscal shocks and thus produce higher levels of budget deficits than unified state governments. Tsebelis and Chang (2004) also find in their analysis of 19 industrialized countries from 1973 to 1995 that countries with multiple veto players have difficulty in altering budget structures, which, in turn, undermines the government’s ability to reduce budget deficits.

    The two theoretical approaches differ in their causal mechanism but they share the same idea that predicts a centralization of political power to reduce budget deficits. Hence, some scholars have attempted to provide a more integrated approach of the two theories. For instance, Hankla (2013) criticizes that most studies only examine the patterns of budget deficits in parliamentary systems and argues that the dynamics of budgetary politics in presidential systems should be differentiated from that of parliamentary systems. Hankla (2013) finds that in presidential systems, unified governments do indeed produce low deficits but even divided governments tend to produce low deficits when fragmentation is high in the legislature. This is because the president’s political survival is not threatened by a fragmented legislature and thus, the president can co-opt small opposition parties when the legislature is fragmented whereas this would not be possible if a single opposition party controls the legislative majority (Hankla 2013). Hankla’s study emphasizes the importance of a central actor, or the president, that would solve the CPR problem but also highlights the impact of different executive-legislative relations in presidential and parliamentary systems on budget outcomes. However, Hankla’s (2013) theory only focuses on the impact of executive strength and legislative fragmentation on budget deficits in presidential systems.

    1For discussions on the economic consequences of budget deficits see for example Gale and Orszag (2003). For political consequences of budget deficits, see Brender and Drazen (2008).  2Roubini and Sachs (1989a/1989b) argue that multiparty governments tend to have higher deficits because coalition partners want to deliver benefits to their constituents at the expense of the total tax burden.  3Although Roubini and Sachs (1989a/1989b) do not mention the term “veto players” in their articles, a part of their argument is similar to that of the veto players theory because they emphasize that multiparty governments tend to be slower in adjusting to fiscal shocks because the budget process is highly inefficient when there are many stakeholders in the government.

    HYPOTHESIS

    In this section, we will derive testable hypotheses from the two contending theories of budget deficits—common pool resource theory and policy inertia theory—in order to test the individual effects of each theory. We will then combine the two approaches to offer a conditional common pool resource theory which predicts that executive strength reduces budget deficits on the condition that the legislature does not have an institutional veto power.

    As stated in the CPR literature on budget deficit, an increase in the executive strength vis-à-vis the legislature decreases budget deficits because the executive, who represents the national constituency and considers the total tax burden, tend to prefer a balanced budget whereas the legislators tend to exploit the budget in order to deliver particularistic benefits to their constituencies. Thus, we expect that:

    On the other hand, the policy inertia theorists argue that budget deficits arise in systems with multiple veto players. In order to change policies, certain veto players must agree to the proposed change and the presence of multiple veto players may stagnate the budgetary policymaking process, which, in turn, would undermine the government’s ability to reduce budget deficits (Tsebelis 2002; Tsebelis and Chang 2004). As for budgetary policymaking, how veto power is distributed among the executive and the legislature can have significant effects on budget outcomes because they can be institutional veto players or actors specified by the country’s constitution that has to agree to a proposed change (Tsebelis 2002, 2) in the budgetary process (Wildavsky 1992). Thus, we can expect budget deficits to be lower in a parliamentary system where there is only one institutional veto player (the executive) because the executive controls the legislative majority. Conversely, budget deficits should be higher in a presidential system compared to a parliamentary system because the executive does not have control over the legislature and thus, there are two institutional veto players (the executive and the legislature). Specifically we expect that,

    Next, we offer a conditional common pool resource theory which combines the two approaches. We predict that there should be an interaction effect of executive strength and parliamentarism/presidentialism on budget deficits. Precisely, the effects of executive strength on budget deficits should be conditional on the presence of legislative veto power because even though the legislators may want to exploit the budget in order to deliver benefits to their constituents at the expense of a balanced budget (Mayhew 1974), they cannot pursue their individual goals if they are not empowered to do so.

    Under parliamentarism, the executive and the legislature are mutually dependent on each other for survival. As a result, legislators under parliamentarism tend to be disciplined by the parties and especially those legislators affiliated with the ruling parties tend to be more disciplined. That is because the prime minister, who is also the leader of the ruling parties, imposes strong discipline on his party members in order to reduce the risk of a defeat in legislative votes, which, in turn, would lead to a dissolution of the cabinet (Linz 1994; Mainwaring and Shugart 1997; Samuels and Shugart 2010). Moreover, the executive’s power to dissolve the legislature is another effective tool to suppress the narrow incentives of individual legislators.Under parliamentarism, the prime minister usually has the power to dissolve the parliament and to call for new elections. This would facilitate executive discipline on the legislature because the legislators should be less likely to challenge the prime minister at the risk of losing their seats in the new elections. It may be possible that the parliament’s vote of no confidence may discipline the executive but the prime minister, who is the leader of the ruling party, would be able to punish his party members for any attempts to dismiss the cabinet.4 Therefore under parliamentarism, the legislature does not have an institutional veto power, and an increase in the executive strength vis-a-vis the legislature (e.g., an increase in seat share of ruling party in the legislature) would thus decrease budget deficits.

    Under parliametnarism, however, the legislature is an institutional veto player because it is independent of the executive to survive (Haggard and McCubbins 2001; Samuels and Shugart 2010). Legislators are thus less disciplined in presidentialism than their counterparts in parliamentarism. Hence the former tend to be more empowered to pursue individual goals. It may be argued that in the unified presidential government where president’s party controls the majority seats in the legislature, the legislature may not be considered as a veto player because of the partisan cohesion of the two branches. Nevertheless, the legislators still tend to be less disciplined than those in parliamentarism because the former have weaker incentives to comply with the president’s interests at the expense of their own interests due to the independence from the executive for survival (Linz 1994; Mainwaring and Shugart 1997). Thus, it can be expected that under parliamentarism, legislators tend to exploit national resources at the expense of a balanced budget in order to deliver benefits to their constituents, irrespective of executive strength over the legislature. Hence we expect that:

    4Empirically, few prime ministers are defeated by a vote of confidence in parliamentary systems regardless of unified or coalition governments. For example, the parliament’s vote of no confidence defeated one prime minister in the United Kingdom since 1924, none in Australia, one in Germany since 1982, one in Greece, etc.

    DATA, MODEL, AND MEASURES

    We test the above hypotheses using cross-national data of 49 countries. The dataset includes Argentina (2002-2004), Armenia (2003-2011), Australia (1999-2011), Austria (1995-2011), Bangladesh (2001-2006, 2009-2011), Belgium (1995-2011), Bolivia (2002-2007), Brazil (1997-2011), Bulgaria (1995-2011), Canada (1995-2011), Chile (2000-2011), Colombia (2001-2011), Denmark (1995-2011), Dominican Republic (2004-2010), Finland (1995-2011), France (1995-2011), Germany (1995-2011), Greece (1995-2011), Guatemala (1995-2011), Honduras (2003-2011), Hungary (1995-2011), Indonesia (1995- 1999, 2002-2011), Italy (1995-2011), Japan (2005-2011), South Korea (1995- 2011), Malaysia (1996-2011), Mexico (1995-2000), the Netherlands (1995- 2011), New Zealand (2001-2011), Nicaragua (1995-2011), Norway (2000-2011), Paraguay (1995-2011), Peru (1995-2011), the Philippines (2000, 2003-2011), Poland (2001-2011), Portugal (1995-2011), Russia (2006-2011), Singapore (1995-2011), Spain (1995-2011), Sri Lanka (1995-2011), Sweden (1995-2011), Switzerland (1995-2011), Thailand (2003-2011), Turkey (2006-2011), United Kingdom (1995-2011), United States (1995-2011), Ukraine (2006-2011), Uruguay (1995-2011), and Venezuela (1995-2005).

    The dependent variable is Deficitit, indicating country i’s budget deficit in year t. We use the World Bank Databank’s Annual Budget Surplus/Deficit data, in which a country’s government budget surplus or deficit is calculated in percentage of gross domestic product (GDP). Because the focus of this study is the level of budget deficits, we inverse the World Bank data in order to assign positive values to deficits and negative values to surpluses. Deficitit ranges from -20.4 to 16.9 with a mean of 1.2.

    Because we use time-series-cross-sectional data and a continuous dependent variable, we construct a fixed-effects regression model to measure the interaction effect of executive strength and executive-legislative relations on budget deficits while controlling for unobservable time-invariant factors in regional contexts (e.g., similar historical experience, culture, etc.). The basic model for country i’s budget deficit in year t is

    where R represents the region-specific dummy variables and ε represents the random error term. A country’s executive strength is affected by how strong the control of the executive over the legislature is and executive-legislative relations are affected mainly by whether a country adopts parliamentarism or presidentialism. We operationalize executive strength, parliamentarism/ presidentialism, and some key control variables as follows.

      >  PARLIAMENTARIANISM/PRESIDENTIALISM

    Using the World Bank’s Database of Political Institutions (DPI 2012), we generate a dummy variable, Parliamentarismit, to indicate whether a country is a parliamentary system or a presidential system. In DPI 2012, countries in which the chief executive is elected and can be easily recalled by the legislature are classified as parliamentarism. We categorize all the other cases, including semi- presidentialism in which the president is elected directly by voters and cannot be easily removed by the legislature, as presidentialism. Parliamentarismit is coded 1 if country i is parliamentarism in year t; 0 otherwise. That is, the variable is coded 0 if country i is presidentialism in year t. Of 652 cases in the dataset 57.8% are parliamentary systems and the rest are presidential systems.

      >  EXECUTIVE STRENGTH

    Executive Strength refers to the percentage of seats that ruling parties take in the legislature. Most preexisting studies use a dummy variable whether or not the ruling parties are in a majority in the legislature to measure the executive strength over the legislature (Lijphart 1984). Instead of the dummy variable, we use the proportion of parliamentary seats, because the latter contains more precise information about the executive strength vis-à-vis the legislature. For example, if ruling parties are in a supermajority in the legislature, they would have less difficulty controlling the legislature than when they are in a bare majority; if they take 25% of the parliamentary seats, they would have more difficulty than when they take 49% of the seats (Shin 2013). This variable ranges from 20.6 to 100, with a mean of 57.2.

    Whether a country adopts parliamentarism or presidentialism is expected to interact with the executive strength in affecting the country’s budget deficit. Because the expectation is that as the executive strength over the legislature increases, budget deficits will decrease in parliamentary systems, we expect Parliamentarismit * Executive Strengthit to correlate negatively with Deficitit.

      >  CONTROL VARIABLES

    In addition to those key variables of interest, several other factors may affect a country’s budget deficit. First, fragmentation in the legislature and in the cabinet should be controlled for. Fragmented legislatures, in which a large number of parties take parliamentary seats, and fragmented cabinets, in which a large number of parties take cabinet posts, tend to decrease the stability of the cabinets (Laver and Schofield 1990; Warwick 1994), and may thus undermine the executive’s ability to reduce budget deficit (Tsebelis 2002; Hankla 2013; Roubini and Sachs 1989a, 1989b; Hallerberg and von Hagen 1999). Legislative fragmentation is the effective number of legislative parties collected by Bormann and Golder (2013); Cabinet fragmentation is obtained from DPI 2012, which is coded 0 if the country has a single-party government, 1 if a two-party government, 2 if a three-party government, and 3 if four-or-more-party government.

    Second, a country’s economic condition could affect the country’s budget deficit (Barro 1979; Lucas and Stokey 1983). The proponents of the tax-smoothing hypothesis argue that macroeconomic conditions may have an effect on budget deficits. We include GDP per Capita (log) to control for the effects of a country’s economic conditions. Data for GDP per capita is obtained from the World Bank Databank.

    Third, political leaders in democracies may be more likely to increase budget deficits than their counterparts in autocracies, because the former tend to have a larger winning coalition (should receive support from a larger number of people) and would thus need to distribute benefits to a broader population (Bueno de Mesquita et al. 2003). We thus use a dummy, Democracy, for 597 cases (out of 652) where countries are classified as a democracy by Cheibub et al. (2010).5

    Finally, because we use time-series cross-national data, we control for time- and region-fixed effects. Dummy variables for observation years are included in the models in order to control for unknown time-invariant year-specific factors that may affect Deficit. Next, to control for unknown time-invariant region-specific factors, dummy variables for world regions are generated because countries in the same world region tend to share similar attributes such as political institutions and to experience the same exogenous shock such as the 1997 Asian financial crisis that may affect the level of budget deficits. Forty-nine countries in the dataset are thus grouped into 11 world regions (see Appendix). Additionally, we also control for year dummies in order to control for unobservable time- specific effects. Specifically, we include year dummies for 1997, 2008, and 2009 because of the significant economic crises that happened during those years and economic crises may cause countries to run higher deficits. We run models with the dummies for world regions (without the dummies for countries) because only a few observations are available for some countries.6

    5A country is democratic if (1) its effective executive is directly elected or selected by an elected assembly, (2) a legislature with multiple parties is elected, and (3) opposition parties or challengers to incumbents are allowed and have realistic chances of taking power (Cheibub et al. 2010).  6For example, there are only three observations (2002-2004) for Argentina.

    EMPIRICAL ANALYSIS

      >  RESULTS

    Table 1 shows the results of our analysis. Executive Strength may be highly correlated with Legislative fragmentation and Cabinet fragmentation because ruling parties tend to take fewer seats in fragmented legislatures, which is likely to lead to a multi-party government to control the majority seats in the legislature (see Shin 2013). Parliamentarism may also be highly correlated with Legislative fragmentation and Cabinet fragmentation for the following two reasons. First, most of the observations (300 out of 377) among parliamentary systems have highly proportional electoral systems, which may be highly correlated with Legislative fragmentation (Lijphart 1990).7 Secondly, coalition governments are more common under Parliamentarism especially when the legislature is highly fragmented. Thus, in order to check for multicollinearity, we run models without Legislative fragmentation and Cabinet fragmentation first.

    [Table 1.] Conditional Common Pool Resource Theory and Budget Deficits

    label

    Conditional Common Pool Resource Theory and Budget Deficits

    In Column 1 of Table 1, we present the results with Executive Strength. Executive Strength is correlated positively with Deficit but is not statistically significant. This finding contradicts the predictions of the common pool resource theory (Hypothesis 1), which would expect executive strength to have a significant impact in decreasing budget deficits. In Column 2 of Table 1, we include Parliamentarism instead of Executive Strength. Parliamentarism also does not have a significant impact on budget deficits. Thus, Column 1 and 2 of Table 1 demonstrates that the results of our analysis contradict the predictions of the common pool resource hypothesis and policy inertia hypothesis.

    Column 3 of Table 1 incorporates both Parliamentarism and Executive Strength, and includes an interaction term of these variables in order to test the conditional common pool resource theory. As expected, as ruling parties take more legislative seats, budget deficits decrease in parliamentary systems; the coefficient on Parliamentarism * Executive Strength is thus negative and significant. Specifically, a unit increase in Executive Strength decreases the level of budget deficits by about 0.08% points under parliamentarism. Additionally, the R2 of Column 3 is about 10% higher than the R2 of Columns 1 and 2, which indicates that our model of conditional common pool resource theory explains the variations of budget deficits better than the models that test the individual effects of the CPR and PI theory. In Column 4 of Table 1, the set of control variables we specified are included in the model. Including the control variables for legislative and cabinet fragmentation in the model does not alter the results substantially. Thus, we can safely discard the multicollinearity concern. The findings of Column 3 and 4 of Table 1 conforms to the conditional common pool resource hypothesis, which predicts that an increase in Executive Strength decreases budget deficits only under Parliamentarism.8

    Some hypothetical examples can help to explain the relevant coefficients by comparing different executive-legislative relations—for example, presidential systems where presidents have strong control over the legislature compared to those where presidents do not control the legislative majority, and parliamentary systems where prime ministers’ parties control a majority of parliamentary seats compared to those where ruling parties are in a minority in the parliament. For example, the level of budget deficit in the presidential system where the president’s party takes 75% of legislative seats is 1.7% higher than that in the presidential system where the ruling party takes 25% of the seats (2.55% versus 0.85%). In contrast, the level of deficit in the parliamentary system where the prime minister’s party takes 75% of parliamentary seats is 2.25% lower than that in the parliamentary system where the ruling party takes 25% of the seats (0.28% versus 2.53%).

    Figure 2 visualizes how an interaction between parliamentarism/ presidentialism and executive’s legislative seats influences the level of budget deficits.

    As the executive controls more seats in the legislature, budget deficits decrease substantially in parliamentary systems while they do not alter significantly in presidential systems. Hence, the gap between presidentialism and parliamentarism widens as the legislative seats controlled by the executive increase. Comparing a few cases in the dataset can help interpret the results. In a presidential system where the ruling parties control over 75% of the parliamentary seats, such as the Philippines in 2006, budget deficits amount to 1.25%. Conversely, deficits amount to -1.91% or a surplus of 1.91% in a parliamentary system where the ruling parties control over 75% of the parliamentary seats, such as Thailand in 2006. The significant difference in the level of budget deficits (1.25% versus -1.91%) indicate that executive strength vis-à-vis the legislature has a significant impact in reducing budget deficits in parliamentary systems whereas such impact is not so significant in presidential systems. We can also compare these results with a set of cases in which the ruling parties control fewer seats. For example, budget deficits in the Philippines actually decreases by 0.05% (from 1.25% to 1.20%) in 2008 compared to 2006 despite the dramatic decrease in the ruling parties’ seat share (from 76.5% to 54.18%). Conversely, budget deficits in Thailand increases by 1.41% (from -1.91% to -0.5%) despite the slight decrease in the ruling parties’ seat share (from 75.4% to 65.83%). The substantive figures demonstrate that the impact of executive strength on budget deficits is significant under parliamentarism while it is not so significant under presidentialism. Thus, our analysis demonstrates that the variations of budget deficits across countries can be explained better with conditional common pool resource theory, rather than with the CPR or PI theory separately.

      >  ROBUSTNESS ANALYSIS

    Although the results of our analysis shown above conform to our predictions of the conditional common pool resource theory, we may suspect that the following issues embedded in analyzing time-series cross-section data may have biased the results of the analysis. First, although we have explained our justification of including region-specific dummies instead of country-specific dummies in our model, there still may be time-invariant factors within each country, rather than the region, which may have an impact on budget deficits. For instance, in some countries unobservable institutional practices may have a significant effect on budget outcomes even under similar institutions. This indicates that our observations may be heteroskedastic and thus our results may be biased. Secondly, budget deficits in year t may be affected by budget deficits in year t-1, which indicates that there may be autoregressive disturbances that would bias the results of our analysis.

    Thus, we check for the robustness of our results from the potential problems mentioned above by the following treatments. First, we rerun our model using the country-fixed effects model. The country-specific fixed effects controls for any country-specific time invariant factors that may have affect budget deficits.9 Second, we include a one-year lagged value of the dependent variable and rerun the model to control for autoregressive disturbances. Lastly, we rerun the models with cluster-robust standard errors (CRSE) at the region level. The cluster-robust standard errors controls for any additional region-specific time invariant factors, such as culture and similar historical experience, which may affect budget deficits. Moreover, the cluster-robust standard errors are not only robust to cluster-heteroskedasticity but also to within-cluster correlation (Cameron and Miller forthcoming). However, since the cluster-robust standard errors is more accurate when the number of clusters is large, we also run the model with clusterrobust standard errors at the country level. The results of our robustness analysis are shown in Table 2.

    [Table 2.] Conditional Common Pool Resource Theory and Budget Deficits (Robustness Analysis)

    label

    Conditional Common Pool Resource Theory and Budget Deficits (Robustness Analysis)

    As shown in Columns 1-4 in Table 2, the results of the robustness rtests are not substantively different from our analysis shown in Table 1. Column 1 shows the results of the country-fixed effects and the coefficient of the interaction term, Executive Strength * Parliamentarism, is actually higher than the estimates in Table 1. In Columns 2 to 4, the inclusion of a lagged dependent variable suppresses the size of the effect of the interaction term. However, the statistical significance of the interaction term is still well over 95%. Lastly, in Columns 3 and 4, inclusion of cluster-robust standard errors at the region and at the country level does not change the results substantially. Therefore, we can infer that the potential bias caused by heteroskedasticity and autoregression in our analysis is negligible.

    7This is also the reason why we do not separately control for electoral systems in our models.  8Since Parliamentarism is coded 1 for parliamentary systems and 0 for presidential systems, it can be predicted that the interaction effect of Executive Strength and Presidentialism is positively correlated with budget deficits.  9Although the random-effects model may be an alternative to fixed-effects model because one of our explanatory variables, Parliamentarism, is time-invariant and may perfectly correlate with country-specific effects. However, we choose to use the fixed-effects model for the following reasons. First, the random-effects model relies on an unrealistic assumption that unobserved country-specific effects are not correlated with the independent variables and thus, the random-effect model is both statistically and theoretically unreliable. Second, the variable of our main interest is the interaction term Executive Strength * Parliamentarism, which is time-variant, and thus the concern for perfect collinearity of the explanatory variable with the country-specific effects can be disregarded.

    CONCLUSION

    In this article, we investigate why countries experience different levels of budget deficits. We argue that the executive control over the legislature decreases budget deficits on the condition that the legislature does not have institutional veto power. Using the cross-national data on budget deficits in 49 countries from 1995 to 2011, we find that an increase in seat share of ruling party in the legislature decreases budget deficits in parliamentary systems; it has little impact in presidential systems.

    We make at least two contributions to the literature on budget deficit with this article. First, we attempt to integrate the logics of the two contending theories— CPR versus PI—on budget deficits in which the CPR theory predicts that a strong executive will decrease deficits and the PI theory predicts that the decrease in the number of veto players will decrease deficits. In this article, we offer a conditional common pool resource theory that contributes to adjudicating this debate by attempting to link the logics of the two theories of budget deficits.

    Secondly, this article demonstrates an interaction effect of executive strength and parliamentarism/presidentialism on budget deficits. While most of the pre- existing literature that study the impacts of political factors on budget deficits focused on either the effects of unified versus divided government or the number of parties in the cabinet/legislature (Roubini and Sachs 1989a, 1989b; Alt and Lowry 1994; Hallerberg and von Hagen 1999; Tsebelis 2002), this article focuses on the effects of the different dynamics of executive-legislative relations in parliamentarism/presidentialism on budget outcomes. Considering that most countries in the world have adopted either one of the two constitutional structures—parliamentarism or presidentialism—the findings of this article may have some practical implications for budgetary politics. For instance, parliamentary systems that suffer from high deficits, such as Greece, may be able to reduce deficits by increasing the seat share of the ruling parties in the parliament through elections or through forming grand coalitions whereas such efforts may not be so effective in reducing budget deficits in presidential systems.

참고문헌
  • 1. Alt James E., Lowry Robert C. 1994 “Divided Government, Fiscal Institutions, and Budget Deficits: Evidence from the States.” [American Political Science Review] Vol.88 P.811-828 google cross ref
  • 2. Barro Robert J. 1979 “On the Determination of the Public Debt.” [Journal of Political Economy] Vol.87 P.940-947 google cross ref
  • 3. Bormann Nils-Christian, Golder Matt 2013 “Democratic Electoral Systems around the World, 1946-2011.” [Electoral Studies] Vol.32 P.360-369 google cross ref
  • 4. Brender Adi, Drazen Allen 2008 “How Do Budget Deficits and Economic Growth Affect Reelection Prospects? Evidence from a Large Panel of Countries.” [American Economic Review] Vol.98 P.2203-2220 google cross ref
  • 5. Bueno de Mesquita Bruce, Smith Alastair, Siverson Randolph M., Morrow James D. 2003 The Logic of Political Survival. google
  • 6. Cameron A. Colin, Miller Douglas L. Forthcoming. “A Practitioner’s Guide to Cluster-Robust Inference.” [Journal of Human Resources] google
  • 7. Carey John M., Shugart Matthew S. 1995 “Incentives to Cultivate a Personal Vote: A Rank Ordering of Electoral Formulas.” [Electoral Studies] Vol.14 P.417-439 google cross ref
  • 8. Cheibub Jose Antonio, Gandhi Jennifer, Vreeland James Raymond 2010 “Democracy and Dictatorship Revisited.” [Public Choice] Vol.143 P.67-101 google cross ref
  • 9. Franzese Robert J. 2002 Macroeconomic Policies of Developed Democracies. google
  • 10. Gale William G., Orszag Peter R. 2003 “Economic Effects of Sustained Budget Deficits.” [National Tax Journal] Vol.56 P.463-485 google
  • 11. Haggard Stephan, McCubbins Mathew D. 2001 “Introduction: Political Institutions and the Determinants of Public Policy.” In Stephan Haggard and Mathew D. McCubbins eds., Presidents, Parliaments, and Policy. google
  • 12. Hallerberg Mark, von Hagen Jurgen 1999 “Electoral Institutions, Cabinet Negotiations, and Budget Deficits in the European Union.” In James M. Poterba ed., Fiscal Institutions and Fiscal Performance. google
  • 13. Hallerberg Mark, Marier Patrik 2004 “Executive Authority, the Personal Vote, and Budget Discipline in Latin American and Caribbean Countries.” [American Journal of Political Science] Vol.48 P.571-587 google cross ref
  • 14. Hallerberg Mark, Strauch Rolf, von Hagen Jurgen 2007 “The Design of Fiscal Rules and Forms of Governance in European Union Countries.” [European Journal of Political Economy] Vol.23 P.338-359 google cross ref
  • 15. Hankla Charles R. 2013 “Fragmented Legislatures and the Budget: Analyzing Presidential Democracies.” [Economics & Politics] Vol.25 P.200-228 google cross ref
  • 16. Hicken Allen, Simmons Joel W. 2008 “The Personal Vote and the Efficacy of Education Spending.” [American Journal of Political Science] Vol.52 P.109-124 google cross ref
  • 17. Kontopoulos Yianos, Perotti Roberto 1999 “Government Fragmentation and Fiscal Policy Outcomes: Evidence from OECD Countries.” In James M. Poterba ed., Fiscal Institutions and Fiscal Performance. google
  • 18. Laakso Markku, Taagepera Rein 1979 “‘Effective’ Number of Parties: A Measure with Application to West Europe.” [Comparative Political Studies] Vol.12 P.3-27 google
  • 19. Laver Michael, Schofield Norman 1990 Multiparty Government: The Politics of Coalition in Europe. google
  • 20. Lijphart Arend 1984 “Measures of Cabinet Durability: A Conceptual and Empirical Evaluation.” [Comparative Political Studies] Vol.17 P.265-279 google cross ref
  • 21. Lijphart Arend 1990 Electoral Systems and Party Systems: A Study of Twenty-Seven Democracies, 1945-1990. google
  • 22. Linz Juan J. 1994 “Presidential or Parliamentary Democracy: Does It Make a Difference?” In Juan J. Linz and Arturo Valenzuela eds., The Failure of Presidential Democracy: The Case of Latin America. google
  • 23. Lucas Robert, Stokey Nancy 1983 “Optimal Fiscal and Monetary Policy in an Economy without Capital.” [Journal of Monetary Economics] Vol.12 P.55-94 google cross ref
  • 24. Mainwaring Scott, Shugart Matthew Soberg 1997 “Conclusion: Presidentialism and the Party System.” In Scott Mainwaring and Matthew Soberg Shugart eds., Presidentialism and Democracy in Latin America. google
  • 25. Mayhew David 1974 Congress: The Electoral Connection. google
  • 26. Ostrom Elinor 1990 Governing the Commons: The Evolution of Institutions for Collective Action. google
  • 27. Roubini Nouriel, Sachs Jeffrey D. 1989a “Political and Economic Determinants of Budget Deficits in the Industrial Democracies.” [European Economic Review] Vol.33 P.908-938 google cross ref
  • 28. Roubini Nouriel, Sachs Jeffrey D. 1989b “Government Spending and Budget Deficits in the Industrial Countries.” [Economic Policy] Vol.4 P.99-132 google cross ref
  • 29. Samuels David J., Shugart Matthew S. 2010 Presidents, Parties, Prime Ministers. google
  • 30. Shin Jae Hyeok 2013 “Cabinet Duration in Presidential Democracies.” [Political Science Quarterly] Vol.128 P.317-339 google cross ref
  • 31. Tsebelis George 2002 Veto Players: How Political Institutions Work. google
  • 32. Tsebelis George, Chang Eric C. C. 2004 “Veto Players and the Structure of Budgets in Advanced Industrialized Countries.” [European Journal of Political Research] Vol.43 P.449-476 google cross ref
  • 33. Von Hagen Jurgen, Harden Ian 1995 “Budget Processes and Commitment to Fiscal Discipline.” [European Economic Review] Vol.39 P.771-779 google cross ref
  • 34. Warwick Paul V. 1994 Government Survival in Parliamentary Democracies. google
  • 35. Wildavsky Aaron 1992 The New Politics of Budgetary Process. google
OAK XML 통계
이미지 / 테이블
  • [ Figure 1. ]  Conditional Common Pool Resource Theory
    Conditional Common Pool Resource Theory
  • [ Table 1. ]  Conditional Common Pool Resource Theory and Budget Deficits
    Conditional Common Pool Resource Theory and Budget Deficits
  • [ Figure 2. ]  Predicted Budget Deficits (% of GDP)
    Predicted Budget Deficits (% of GDP)
  • [ Table 2. ]  Conditional Common Pool Resource Theory and Budget Deficits (Robustness Analysis)
    Conditional Common Pool Resource Theory and Budget Deficits (Robustness Analysis)
(우)06579 서울시 서초구 반포대로 201(반포동)
Tel. 02-537-6389 | Fax. 02-590-0571 | 문의 : oak2014@korea.kr
Copyright(c) National Library of Korea. All rights reserved.