This article empirically investigates long-run and short-run economic linkages between Korea and the US. A cointegrated vector autoregressive analysis of the two countries’ quarterly data reveals three theory-consistent long-run relationships: the first relationship accords with a loose-form real interest parity condition, the second corresponds to a real exchange rate equation and the third is interpreted as a current account equation. A vector equilibrium correction system is then estimated in order to reveal the structure of the underlying short-run dynamics. Finally, the system’s forecasting performance is discussed. Overall, the study indicates that the two economies have been closely related with each other through interest and foreign exchange rate channels.
As the international integration of goods, services and assets markets has proceeded, linkages among economies in terms of prices, interest rates and exchange rates have been broadly studied. Many recent studies on international integration in the Pacific Basin have concentrated on linkages between the region’s developing economies versus Japan and the US. According to the results of these studies, there appears substantial increasing integration of domestic and international goods and financial markets. For instance, Glick and Hutchison (1990) find that the degree of linkage between domestic real interest rates in Pacific Basin countries and those in the US increased as financial liberalization in the region proceeded. Kim (1998) reveals that the degree of international capital mobility has increased rapidly in Korea since the 1980s. Ji and Kim (2009) examine the linkage of real interest rates of a group of Pacific Basin countries from 1980 to 2006 and find that the degree of capital market integration has rapidly increased since the Asian Financial Crisis of 1997-1998. In light of recent advances in market integration in the Asia-Pacific region, this article makes an empirical investigation of long-run and short-run economic linkages between Korea and the US, using a cointegrated vector autoregressive (VAR) methodology developed for the analysis of nonstationary time series data. This introductory section, as a background study, gives a review of the Korean economy as well as the related literature, then moves on to the account of our contributions to the research field of Asia-Pacific economic relationships.
When the Korean economy grew rapidly during the 1960s and 1970s, the financial sector was treated as a means of allocating available financial resources to the priority sectors, in particular, export sectors. Financial liberalization policies were adopted in the early 1980s, when the government launched a comprehensive program of economic liberalization and opening. While traderelated finance and foreign direct investment had already been mostly liberalized, flows of both portfolio investment and short-term capital were gradually liberalized. Thus, during the 1980s, the government occasionally controlled the international capital flows, considering the balance of payments, exchange rate and monetary management.
The Korean won was pegged to the US dollar until March 1980, when the government switched to a multicurrency basket peg (MCBP) system. The exchange rate was determined as a weighted average of the SDR basket and Korea’s own basket of currencies, with the government influencing the exchange rate. In February 1990, the MCBP system was replaced by a market average rate (MAR) system. The “market average rate” of the won against the US dollar was calculated by taking a weighted average of exchange rates. The market average rate became the basic rate of the following business day, and the exchange rate was allowed to fluctuate within a certain band around the basic rate. As Jwa (1994) points out, concern over possible exchange rate appreciation, especially during the late 1980s, turned out to be one of the main impediments to the liberalization of capital flows, but with the introduction of the MAR system, a more conducive environment was created for capital flow liberalization. The government eventually adopted a flexible exchange rate system in December 1997, at the onset of the financial crisis.
Until 1980, interest rates were strictly controlled by the authorities in Korea. The government started to deregulate interest rates from the early 1980s as inflationary expectations became low due to successful stabilization policies. The call rate (money market rate) was liberalized in 1984. The favorable situation in the form of price stability, high growth, and current account improvement in the late 1980s led the Korean government to continue financial liberalization. National savings exceeded domestic investment, which resulted in narrowing interest differentials between regulated rates and free market rates. In the early 1990s, the government further deregulated interest rates. By 1993, interest rates on the borrowing and lending of financial institutions were almost completely deregulated.
Let us turn to a real interest rate parity hypothesis, which is seen as one of our primary empirical interests and referred to as a real interest parity condition in this paper. Early studies using a classic regression analysis showed that the condition did not empirically hold; see, for example, Cumby and Obstfeld (1984), Mark (1985) and Cumby and Mishkin (1986). More recent studies utilizing the cointegration methodology obtained more favorable, but still
For Asian developing economies, several studies lead to
In regard to the purchasing power parity or the stationarity of the real exchange rate, there is a lot of research on the won-dollar exchange rate, whose results are
As the real exchange rate often appears to be non-stationary, the existing cointegration studies in international finance tend to focus on linkages between the real exchange rate and macroeconomic fundamentals such as inflation and interest rates. Some studies have not been favorable of such linkages, while others have shown evidence for stable linkages. Meese and Rogoff (1988) find little evidence of a stable relationship between real interest rate differentials and real exchange rates in Germany, Japan, the UK and the US. Thus, they suggest that real disturbances (such as productivity shocks) may be a major source of exchange rate volatility. Edison and Pauls (1993) show that real exchange rates and real interest rates are not cointegrated with each other. Cheng (1999) examines the relationships between exchange rates, relative prices, and interest rates for Japan and the US. Causality running from the interest rate to the exchange rate is found in the short run, while causality running from the price ratio to the exchange rate via the interest rate is found in the long run. MacDonald and Nagayasu (1998) find two cointegrating vectors on the domestic price and the exchange rate from a set of the yen–dollar exchange rate, home and foreign prices, and home and foreign interest rates. Juselius and MacDonald (2004) show that key parity conditions between the US and Japan did not hold as stationary relations, which, they suggest, arises from the non-stationarity of the real exchange rate. Kurita (2007) investigates theory-consistent cointegrating relationships between the real yen-dollar rate, interest rate differentials and other economic fundamentals. The current account balance in Japan appears to play an important role in determining the real exchange rate along with the interest rates. In regard to Korea, there are several studies. Kim (1995) shows that the won-dollar exchange rate has a stable long run relationship with the current account balance and interest rate differentials. Lee (1997) and Lee and Choi (1998) incorporate several macroeconomic variables to explain and/or forecast the won-dollar exchange rate. Kim and Kwon (2003) successfully apply the real interest differential theory of Frankel (1979) to the Korean won exchange rate determination.
The review of the Korean economy and literature given above, overall, leads to a motivation for the empirical exploration in this article. It seems that the literature on the real interest parity, exchange rate determination and current account equation is separated in most cases, although all of these three themes are deeply related to important international financial aspects of the economies in question.
The rest of this article is organized as follows. Section II reviews a cointegrated VAR model and economic implications of cointegrating vectors, and Section III then provides a canonical model on a loose-form real interest parity, real exchange rate behavior and current account. Section IV presents an overview of the data, and Section V performs a cointegrated VAR analysis of the data in order to reveal long-run economic relationships. Section VI estimates a parsimonious vector equilibrium correction system so as to investigate the underlying short-run dynamics. The overall summary and conclusion are given in Section VII. All the numerical analyses and graphics in this article use
1Exceptional works using the cointegrated VAR methodology are, among others, Kurita (2007) on exchange rates and the current account in Japan, and Choo and Kurita (2011) on monetary interaction aspects in Korea.
Ⅱ. Cointegrated VAR Model and Long-Run Economic Linkages
This section briefly reviews the likelihood-based analysis of a cointegrated VAR model for time series data of integrated of order 1, denoted by
where
The cointegrating rank
Ⅲ. Real Interest Parity, Real Exchange Rate Behavior and Current Account
This section introduces a canonical economic model, which is subject to the study of long-run economic relationships using Equation (1). We consider two countries: home and foreign. The
where
Equation (4) is called the real interest parity. Let
denote an expected change in the real exchange rate. The
We may also incorporate a risk premium into Equation (3), and thus into Equations (4) and (5) as well, allowing for the
where a constant term
Let us then turn to a set of equations for the real exchange rate and the current account balance, which is denoted by
where
Suppose that
where
where
This section gives an overview of the time series data in Korea (the home country) and the US (the foreign country), running from the first quarter in 1981 to the first quarter in 2010 (denoted 1981.1-2010.1 hereafter). The overview helps us to explore the possibility that such long-run economic linkages as shown in Equations (6), (9) and (10) in the previous section, may empirically hold in the data for the two countries. A subsequent formal analysis of long-run relationships is performed in the next section. See Appendix A for details on the data.
Figure 1(a) presents a long-term interest rate differential (
Figure 1(d) presents the real won-dollar rate (
2Note that a rise in pppt denotes a real appreciation of the Korean won. 3Note that when the risk premium ϕt is high, the domestic interest rate it is low and/or the foreign interest rate i*t is high, according to the definition on the risk premium ϕt in Equation (8). 4That is, we suppose that an improvement in the current account cat of the home economy is positively related to either a rise in the risk premium of the foreign economy, ϕt, or a fall in the risk premium of the home economy, –ϕt.
Ⅴ. Cointegrated VAR Analysis of Korea-US Linkages
Motivated by the arguments in Sections III and IV, we select the set of variables to be analyzed as follows:
which leads to a five-dimensional VAR system formulated as Equation (1). Other variables like income, wealth and depreciation rate are not explicitly taken into account here, as they can be empirically irrelevant in the context of a cointegration analysis.
The sample period for estimation is 1981.1-2010.1, thus the number of observations available for estimation is 117. The lag length of the VAR model is set at 3 based on
and zero otherwise.
[Table 1] Residual Diagnostic Tests for the Unrestricted VAR Model
Residual Diagnostic Tests for the Unrestricted VAR Model
Table 1 presents a set of diagnostic tests on the residuals of the unrestricted VAR model. The first panel reports the test results in the form
2. Determination of the Cointegrating Rank
Table 2 presents the log
[Table 2] Determination of the Cointegrating Rank
Determination of the Cointegrating Rank
The log
3. Fully Specified Adjustment and Cointegrating Vectors
A series of trials, motivated by the discussion in Section III and the data overview in Section IV, have led to a set of acceptable joint restrictions as follows:
Asterisks in
matrices denote coefficients on which no restriction is imposed, while
, most of which are rounded to the second decimal place, are reported in Table 3, together with the corresponding log
[Table 3] Fully Specified Adjustment and Cointegrating Vectors
Fully Specified Adjustment and Cointegrating Vectors
The restricted cointegrating relationships in the table are denoted by
which corresponds to the loose-form real interest parity given by Equation (6). It is noteworthy that such a simple linear combination of
The second cointegrating relationship is, according to Table 3, given by
which coincides with Equation (9), thus being interpreted as the modified
This estimate indicates that expectation adjustments towards the PPP level occur gradually, which seems to agree with our intuition. As
Finally, the third relationship is
which is interpreted as a current account equation given by Equation (10). The interpretation is based on the conjecture that a rise in
In addition, as a complementary comparative study, the same analysis as above is conducted using the VAR model excluding all the blip and impulse dummy variables, with the result that batteries of fairly similar coefficients are obtained. See Appendix B for a table recording these coefficients. Overall, the similarity between the estimates for the two VAR models seems to support the validity of the adjustment and cointegrating structure reported in this section. As a caveat, let us recall that it is not justifiable to try to make reliable inferences solely based on this auxiliary VAR model, whose estimated innovations are much affected by large-scale outliers triggered by various historical events. See Sub-section 1 for details.
Ⅵ. A Vector Equilibrium Correction System
We are now in a position to estimate a parsimonious vector equilibrium correction system based on the cointegration analysis above. Removing insignificant regressors from the model step by step, we have arrived at a parsimonious system as follows:
where the figures in the parentheses are standard errors and all the dummy variables are omitted for the sake of simplicity in exposition. The adjustment structure of the parsimonious system is in accord with that found in Table 3.
According to system (11),
Finally, Figure 3 displays sequences of 1-step forecasts of
This paper shows that the estimated cointegrated VAR system, which consists of interest rate differentials, the real won-dollar rate and several macroeconomic variables of Korea and the US, encompasses three long-run relationships interpretable from economic theory. The first relationship agrees with a loose-form real interest parity condition, the second is consistent with a real exchange rate equation and the third is viewed as a current account equation. A parsimonious vector equilibrium correction system is subsequently estimated so that the structure of the underlying short-run dynamics can be inspected. Lastly, the study demonstrates that the preferred parsimonious system is informative as a macroeconomic forecasting device. Overall, the study supports the view that the two economies have been closely associated with each other through interest and foreign exchange rate channels. The results presented in this article are, as a whole, seen as useful empirical information for policy makers as well as macroeconomists who are interested in the underlying interdependent relationships in the Asia-Pacific region.