검색 전체 메뉴
PDF
맨 위로
OA 학술지
The Determinants of South Korea’s Trade Balance: A Cointegrating Regression Approach
  • 비영리 CC BY-NC
ABSTRACT
The Determinants of South Korea’s Trade Balance: A Cointegrating Regression Approach
KEYWORD
Trade Balance , Cointegrating Regression
  • Ⅰ. Introduction

    This paper investigates the relationship between the trade balance, foreign income, money supply, real exchange rate, and domestic income of South Korea’s economy. This inquiry is worthwhile because if exchange rate depreciation does not improve the trade balance, stabilization packages that include some exchange rate realignment cannot be justified. It is important for policymakers to understand whether changes in real exchange rates can be used as a policy tool to manipulate trade flows.

    This study differs from the extant literature in at least two dimensions. First, we focus exclusively on South Korea because of its important trade and economic characteristics. South Korea is Asia’s fourth-largest economy and the world’s 12th-largest economy measured by purchasing power parity. South Korea is a member of the United Nations, WTO, OECD, and G-20 economies and a founding member of APEC and the East Asia Summit. South Korea is an Asian Tiger and to date the only developed country included in the Next Eleven countries. The South Korean economy is export-driven and heavily dependent on international trade. In 2010, South Korea was the world’s sixthlargest exporter and 10th-largest importer. However, few studies examine the relationship between trade balance and its determinants in South Korea.

    Second, we have adopted three fully efficient estimation methods: fully modified OLS (FMOLS) (Phillips and Hansen, 1990), canonical cointegrating regression (CCR) (Park, 1992), and dynamic OLS (DOLS) (Saikkonen, 1992; Stock and Watson, 1993). The FMOLS procedure involves the use of Wald tests, where the resulting test statistics are “fully modified” by semi-parametric corrections for serial correlation and for endogeneity. This fully modified procedure has been found to work well in finite samples. The CCR procedure also removes the long-run dependence between the cointegrating equation and stochastic regressors’ innovations. In addition, the key advantage of the DOLS procedure is that it allows for the presence of a mix of I(0) and I(1) variables in the cointegrated system. DOLS corrects for potential endogeneity problems and small sample bias and provides estimates of the cointegrating vector that are asymptotically efficient.

    We organize the rest of the paper as follows. In the next sections, we present a theoretical background of the Keynsian view, J-curve, and Marshall-Lerner condition. Section III provides a brief overview of selected literature. Section IV provides a theoretical framework. Section V discusses the data and reports results. Section VI concludes and offers policy recommendations.

    Ⅱ. Marshall-Lerner Condition, J-Curve and the Keynsian View

    Given that an individual country is small relative to the rest of the world, one condition that is required for a successful depreciation is the fulfillment of the Marshall-Lerner condition, i.e., sum of import and export demand elasticities exceeding unity. However, the Marshall-Lerner condition is considered a long-run condition. The J-Curve concept, which was introduced in 1973 by Magee (1973), asserts that it is possible for depreciation to worsen the trade balance in the short-run before showing improvement.

    According to the Keynesian approach, exchange rate depreciation affects the relative prices of domestic goods in domestic currency. This reduction produces two forms of direct effects. First, there is an income effect, which would increase absorption, and then reduce the trade balance. Second, there is a substitution effect that causes a shift in the composition of demand from foreign goods to domestic goods that is the exchange rate change causes an expenditure-substituting effect.

    Ⅲ. Literature Review

    Despite popular belief that depreciation can improve the trade balance, the empirical studies tend to suggest mixed results (See Table 1). For example, Duasa (2007) examines the relationships between trade balance, real exchange rates, income, and money supply in Malaysia. Using an autoregressive distributed lag (ARDL) approach to cointegration, those variables are found to be cointegrated, and the study suggests that the Marshall-Lerner condition does not hold in the long-run for Malaysia. Duasa (2007) adds that the Malaysian trade balance or balance of payments should be viewed from absorption and monetary approaches. However, Duasa’s (2007) study is not a sufficient work on the specification of trade balance. It is worth noting that the foreign income is ignored by Duasa (2007) without further clarification. It may raise a question about the biases of omitting other relevant variables in modeling trade balance behavior.

    [Table 1] Comparison of Previous Literature

    label

    Comparison of Previous Literature

    Bentum-Ennin (2008) analyzes the responsiveness of the balance of trade to changes in real exchange rates. He examines the time pattern of this response to verify the existence of the J-curve phenomenon in Ghana. He finds that the real exchange rate has a positive long-run relationship with Ghana’s trade balance, demonstrating that depreciation leads to an improvement in the trade balance.

    Hsing (2008) finds evidence of a J-curve for Chile, Ecuador, and Uruguay and a lack of support for a J-curve for Argentina, Brazil, Colombia, and Peru. An increase in real income in the home country would improve trade balances for Brazil and Ecuador and worsen trade balances for Argentina, Chile, Colombia, Peru, and Uruguay. An increase in real income in the U.S. would improve the trade balance for Argentina, Chile, Colombia, Peru, and Uruguay and worsen trade balances for Brazil and Ecuador.

    Makin (2008) evaluates China’s exchange rate policy and current account surplus in the context of its rapid development under the hypothesis that undervaluation of the Yuan against major currencies is central to any explanation of global imbalances. He argues that the currency misalignment has resulted in China’s industrialized trading partners, notably the U.S. and the European Union, simultaneously experiencing larger bilateral current account deficits with China, lower output, lower saving, and higher investment. He suggests that significant appreciation in China’s exchange rate would simultaneously reduce China’s huge trade surplus and the bilateral deficits of its trading partners.

    Recently, Waliullah et al. (2010) examine the short-run and long-run relationships between the trade balance, income, money supply, and real exchange rate in Pakistan’s economy. Their results provide persuasive evidence that money supply and income are prominent in determining the behavior of the trade balance. The exchange rate regime can help improve the trade balance, but will have a weaker influence than growth and monetary policy.

    Surprising, there is no existing literature on South Korea’s trade balance. Also, there is no previous paper using cointegrating regression methods as econometric analysis tools. To the best of our knowledge, this paper is the first to investigate the determinants of South Korea’s trade balance using cointegrating regression methods.

    Ⅳ. Theoretical Framework

    Our model begins with the assumption that the quantity of imported goods demanded depends on the domestic income and the relative price of imported goods:

    image

    where IMd is the quantity of domestic imports, Yd is domestic income, and PIMd is the price of imported goods relative to domestically produced goods. Likewise, the foreign import function is as follows:

    image

    where IMw is the quantity of foreign imports, Yw is the real income in the world, and PIMw is the relative price of imports abroad.

    The quantities of goods available for export depend on the relative price of exports and on the level of production:

    image
    image

    where EXd and EXw are the supplies of domestic and foreign country’s exports, respectively.

    A monetary variable, M, is included in the import demand and export supply functions. The extended import demand and export supply functions are as follows:

    image
    image

    In the following equilibrium conditions, we can determine quantities and prices:

    image
    image
    image
    image

    The value of the domestic trade balance is as follows:

    image

    where EXd*PEXw is the value of domestic exports and IMd*REER*PEXw is the value of domestic imports. Taking into consideration the equations expressed above on the balance of trade relations, we formulate two versions of money supply as follows:

    Model 1 has the form:

    image

    Model 2 has the form:

    image

    Here, TB is trade balance, M1 is the narrow money supply, M3 is the broad money supply, IP is a measure of domestic income, WORLD is a measure of foreign income, REER is a measure of the real effective exchange rate, is an error term, and t denotes time.1 The reasons for the exclusion of the foreign money supply as well as inclusion of South Korea’s money supply as a variable in regression are as follows. First, we follow the works of Duasa (2007), Bentum-Ennin (2008), and Waliullah et al. (2010). Second, imports of intermediate and capital goods are important in export production. Meanwhile, poor export performance reduces foreign exchange availability, leading to import compression. Availability of domestic credit may be expected to have an impact on imports and exports. Therefore, we include South Korea’s money supply in regression.

    1In order to allow for a currency substitution between South Korea and the rest of the world, we used a measure of the real effective exchange rate. The traditional IMF measure of the real effective exchange rate uses a weighted average of foreign prices, with weights reflecting the home country’s bilateral trade with each foreign country. The advantage of this definition is that it enables a comparison of domestic and international prices over time.

    Ⅴ. Data and Empirical Results

       1. Data

    Table 2 contains descriptions and sources of the variables used in this research. Data used for the empirical exercise are monthly for the period of January 1991–January 2011 and are obtained from the OECD Main Economic Indicators. In the Appendix, we provide complete details on the different variables. All variables are seasonal adjustments of the data. To reduce heteroscedasticity, all variables are transformed into natural logarithms. Time series plots of the variables are presented in Figure 1.

    [Table 2] Definitions of Variables and Data Sources

    label

    Definitions of Variables and Data Sources

       2. Unit Root Tests

    Properties of the variables must be investigated in order to avoid the possibility of spurious regressions. We use augmented Dickey and Fuller (1979, ADF), Phillips and Perron (1988, PP), Kwiatkowski-Phillips-Schmidt-Shin (1992, KPSS), and Elliott-Rothenberg-Stock point optimal (ERS, 1996) unit root tests. All unit root tests (except KPSS) in our study have a null hypothesis that the series in question has a unit root against the alternative of stationarity. In contrast, the null of KPSS states that the variable displays stationarity. Results of the unit root tests are presented in Table 3 and, in most cases, seem to indicate that all variables are integrated of order 1, that is, I(1).

       3. Cointegration Tests

    To test for a long-run relationship among the variables, we apply the Johansen (1988) cointegration tests, the residual-based tests of Engle and Granger (1987) and Phillips and Ouliaris (1990), and Park’s added variables test (Park, 1992). Results from the Johansen cointegration tests are presented in Table 4. Both the maximum eigenvalue and the trace statistics indicate there is one cointegration vector in Model 1 and Model 2. On the other hand, the cointegration results tabulated by Engle and Granger, and the Phillips and Ouliaris residual-based tests are in Tables 5 and 6. For both Models 1 and 2, we reject the null hypothesis of no cointegration.

    [Table 4] Johansen Cointegration Test

    label

    Johansen Cointegration Test

    [Table 5] Engle and Granger Cointegration Test

    label

    Engle and Granger Cointegration Test

    [Table 6] Phillips-Ouliaris Cointegration Test

    label

    Phillips-Ouliaris Cointegration Test

    Finally, the results of Park’s added variables test are reported in Table 7. Park (1992) outlines a test of the null hypothesis of cointegration against the alternative of no cointegration. We find that the Chi-square test statistics do not reject the null hypothesis of no cointegration. Hence, trade balance, real money supply, domestic income, exchange rate, and foreign income are cointegrated.

    [Table 7] Park Added Variables Cointegration Test

    label

    Park Added Variables Cointegration Test

       4. Cointegrating Regression

    In Tables 8 and 9, results of three different estimators (FMOLS, CCR, and DOLS) are reported for Model 1 and Model 2, respectively. We find that WORLD has a statistically significant and positive impact on money demand. For example, the elasticity of WORLD ranges from 1.923 to 2.146, implying that a 1% increase in WORLD leads to, at most, a 2.146% increase in Model 1. Meanwhile, the elasticity of WORLD ranges from 1.519 to 1.636 in Model 2. Since the response is relatively elastic, South Korea’s trade balance is likely to improve from growth in foreign income.

    Additionally, IP has a statistically significant and negative effect in both Models 1 and 2. For instance, a 1% increase in IP decreases TB by 1.017 to 1.132% in Model 1 and 0.646 to 0.659% in Model 2. IP is a negative sign, which is consistent with the theory. According to theory, it has a negative impact in country trade balances because an increase in our domestic level of income causes less availability of goods to export.

    The impact of the REER on the trade balance is negative and statistically significant. It suggests that the Marshall-Lerner condition holds in the long-run. The depreciation of domestic currency by 1% on average improves the trade balance by 0.630-0.675% and 0.581-0.628% as suggested by Model 1 and Model 2, respectively. It indicates that the sum of elasticities of exports and imports exceeds unity in the long-run and that depreciation improves the trade balance.

    [Table 8] Cointegrating Regression for Model 1

    label

    Cointegrating Regression for Model 1

    [Table 9] Cointegrating Regression for Model 2

    label

    Cointegrating Regression for Model 2

       5. Granger Causality Test

    Tables 10 and 11 report the results of short-run and long-run Granger causality for Model 1 and Model 2, respectively. Beginning with the short-run results, the chi-square tests of the explanatory variables indicate the significance of the short-run causal effects. We can find a unidirectional causality from REER and WORLD to TB.

    [Table 10] Granger Causality Tests for Model 1

    label

    Granger Causality Tests for Model 1

    In terms of long-run results, t-statistics for coefficients of the lagged error-correction terms indicate the significance of the long-run causal effects. The coefficient of the one-period-lagged error correction term is statistically significant with a negative sign in the trade balance equation for Models 1 and 2. This result suggests that all variables Granger-cause South Korea’s TB in the long-run.

    [Table 11] Granger Causality Tests for Model 2

    label

    Granger Causality Tests for Model 2

       6. Generalized Impulse Response Functions

    The generalized impulse response results are depicted in Figures 2 and 3. The months after the impulse shocks are shown on the horizontal axis. The vertical axis measures the magnitude of the response. An appreciation will immediately deteriorate South Korea’s trade balance for about three months, after which it briefly improves, indicating some form of the inverted J-curve effect. Subsequently, the trade balance deteriorates again and remains in deficit.

    Moreover, the trade balance reacts to domestic income innovations as it responds negatively. This result conforms to the Keynesian view that a rise in domestic income encourages more demand for imported goods and therefore worsens the trade balance.

       7. Forecast Error Variance Decomposition

    Forecast error variance decomposition provides an optimal measure of the amount of forecast error variance decomposition for each variable that would result from a different possible ordering of the variables. Table 12 reports the results of the forecast error variance decomposition in Model 1. We find that the impact of D(WORD) can explain 18.816% of the forecast error variance of trade balance in the long-run. Results of the forecast error variance decomposition for Model 2 appear in Table 13. After 18 months, the impact of D(REER) explains 26.101% of the forecast error variance of trade balance in Model 2.

    [Table 12] Forecast Error Variance Decomposition for Model 1

    label

    Forecast Error Variance Decomposition for Model 1

    [Table 13] Forecast Error Variance Decomposition for Model 2

    label

    Forecast Error Variance Decomposition for Model 2

       8. Comparison of Results with the Previous Literature

    On the basis of the cointegration tests results, we conclude that South Korea’s trade balance and its determinants are cointegrated. Also, Duasa (2007) shows that there is a cointegration relationship among the variables using a bound testing approach for Malaysia. Consistent with our finding, Bentum-Ennin (2008) finds that there is a J-curve effect in Ghana. Moreover, our finding for the Marshall-Lerner condition is consistent with that found by Waliullah et al. (2010). However, the Marshall-Lerner condition does not hold from the work of Duasa (2007), which utilizes an ARDL approach.

    Ⅵ. Conclusions and Policy Implications

    This paper has examined the relationships between South Korea’s balance of trade and each of its four important determinants. The results suggest a long-run relationship between trade balance, real effective exchange rate, foreign income, money supply, and domestic income. Upon estimating the trade balance model using three different estimators (FMOLS, CCR and DOLS), it was clear that foreign income is the most important determinant of the trade balance, followed by domestic income and real effective exchange rate.

    Two policy implications emerge from our analysis. First, the impact of the exchange rate on the trade balance is negative and statistically significant. This finding suggests that the Marshall-Lerner condition holds in the long-run in the case of South Korea. Appreciation of South Korea’s currency by 1% on average weakens its trade balance by 0.675% and 0.581%. This finding indicates that the sum of elasticities of exports and imports exceeds unity in the longrun. The exchange rate is a potent policy tool to realign South Korea’s balance of trade.

    Finally, consistent with the Keynesian view, increases in domestic income will encourage the general public to purchase more imported goods and thus worsen South Korea’s trade balance. There is a need to search out import substations to fill the import demand and to establish policies regarding improvement in the volume of qualitative exports. Domestic supply increases and a regulatory framework to assure supply of goods are needed.

참고문헌
  • 1. Bentum-Ennin I. (2008) “Balance of Trade and Exchange Rate: An Econometric Investigation into the J-Curve Phenomenon in Ghana” [ICFAI Journal of Applied Economics] Vol.VII P.31-49 google
  • 2. Dickey D. A., Fuller W. A. (1979) “Distribution of the Estimators for Autoregressive Time Series with A Unit Root” [Journal of the American Statistical Society] Vol.75 P.427-431 google
  • 3. Duasa J. (2007) “Determinants of Malaysia Trade Balance: An ARDL Bound Testing Approach” [Global Economic Review] Vol.36 P.89-102 google cross ref
  • 4. Elliott G., Rothenberg T. J., Stock J. H. (1996) “Efficient Tests for An Autoregressive Unit Root” [Econometrica] Vol.64 P.813-836 google cross ref
  • 5. Engle R. F., Granger C. W. J. (1987) “Cointegration and Error Correction: Representation, Estimation and Testing” [Econometrica] Vol.55 P.251-276 google cross ref
  • 6. Hsing Yu (2008) “A Study of the J-Curve for Seven Selected Latin American Countries” [Global Economy Journal] Vol.8 P.1-12 google cross ref
  • 7. Johansen S. (1988) “Statistical Analysis of Cointegration Vectors” [Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control] Vol.12 P.231-254 google cross ref
  • 8. Kwiatkowski D., Phillips P. C. B., Schmidt P., Shin Y. (1992) “Testing the Null Hypothesis of Stationarity Against The Alternative of A Unit Root: How Sure Are We That Economic Time Series Have a Unit Root” [Journal of Econometrics] Vol.54 P.159-178 google cross ref
  • 9. MacKinnon J. G., Haug A. A., Michelis L. (1999) “Numerical Distribution Functions of Likelihood Ratio Tests for Cointegration” [Journal of Applied Econometrics] Vol.14 P.563-577 google cross ref
  • 10. Magee S. P. (1973) “Currency contracts, pass-through, and the J-curve” [Brookings Papers of Economic Activity] Vol.1 P.303-323 google cross ref
  • 11. Makin Anthony J. (2008) “The Inflexible Yuan and Global Imbalances” [Global Economy Journal] Vol.8 P.1-10 google cross ref
  • 12. Park Joon Y. (1992) “Canonical Cointegrating Regressions” [Econometrica] Vol.60 P.119-143 google cross ref
  • 13. Phillips P. C. B., Ouliaris S. (1990) “Asymptotic Properties of Residual Based Tests for Cointegration” [Econometrica] Vol.58 P.165-193 google cross ref
  • 14. Phillips P. C. B., Perron P. (1988) “Testing for A Unit Root in Time Series Regressions” [Biometrika] Vol.75 P.335-346 google cross ref
  • 15. Phillips P. C. B., Hansen B. E. (1990) “Statistical Inference in Instrumental Variables Regression with I(1) Processes” [Review of Economic Studies] Vol.57 P.99-125 google cross ref
  • 16. Saikkonen P. (1992) “Estimation and Testing of Cointegrated Systems By An Autoregressive Approximation” [Econometric Theory] Vol.8 P.1-27 google cross ref
  • 17. Stock J. H., Watson M. W. (1993) “A Simple Estimator of Cointegrating Vectors in Higher Order Integrated Systems” [Econometrica] Vol.61 P.783-820 google cross ref
  • 18. Waliullah Kakar, M. K., Kakar R., Khan W. (2010) “The Determinants of Pakistan’s Trade Balance: An ARDL Cointegration Approach” [The Lahore Journal of Economics] Vol.15 P.1-26 google
OAK XML 통계
이미지 / 테이블
  • [ Table 1 ]  Comparison of Previous Literature
    Comparison of Previous Literature
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ Table 2 ]  Definitions of Variables and Data Sources
    Definitions of Variables and Data Sources
  • [ Figure 1 ]  Time Series Plots of Variables (on log scale)
    Time Series Plots of Variables (on log scale)
  • [ Table 3 ]  Unit Root Tests
    Unit Root Tests
  • [ Table 4 ]  Johansen Cointegration Test
    Johansen Cointegration Test
  • [ Table 5 ]  Engle and Granger Cointegration Test
    Engle and Granger Cointegration Test
  • [ Table 6 ]  Phillips-Ouliaris Cointegration Test
    Phillips-Ouliaris Cointegration Test
  • [ Table 7 ]  Park Added Variables Cointegration Test
    Park Added Variables Cointegration Test
  • [ Table 8 ]  Cointegrating Regression for Model 1
    Cointegrating Regression for Model 1
  • [ Table 9 ]  Cointegrating Regression for Model 2
    Cointegrating Regression for Model 2
  • [ Table 10 ]  Granger Causality Tests for Model 1
    Granger Causality Tests for Model 1
  • [ Table 11 ]  Granger Causality Tests for Model 2
    Granger Causality Tests for Model 2
  • [ Figure 2 ]  Plot of the Generalized Impulse Response of TB to REER Function for Model 1
    Plot of the Generalized Impulse Response of TB to REER Function for Model 1
  • [ Figure 3 ]  Plot of the Generalized Impulse Response of TB to REER Function for Model 2
    Plot of the Generalized Impulse Response of TB to REER Function for Model 2
  • [ Table 12 ]  Forecast Error Variance Decomposition for Model 1
    Forecast Error Variance Decomposition for Model 1
  • [ Table 13 ]  Forecast Error Variance Decomposition for Model 2
    Forecast Error Variance Decomposition for Model 2
(우)06579 서울시 서초구 반포대로 201(반포동)
Tel. 02-537-6389 | Fax. 02-590-0571 | 문의 : oak2014@korea.kr
Copyright(c) National Library of Korea. All rights reserved.