검색 전체 메뉴
PDF
맨 위로
OA 학술지
North-South Trade and Tariff Policya
  • 비영리 CC BY-NC
ABSTRACT
North-South Trade and Tariff Policya
KEYWORD
North-South Trade , Economic Growth , Tariff , Subsidy
  • Ⅰ. Introduction

    Despite the current trend of globalization, tariffs are still one of the most important trade policy measures for both developed and developing countries.1 Since the establishment of the WTO (World Trade Organization), tariff rates have been reduced throughout the world. Have these tariff reductions accelerated economic growth? How does the effect differ between developed countries and developing countries? How do these tariffs affect economic growth driven by technological progress (an engine of growth)? How do these tariffs affect the wage differential between developing and developed countries? The main objective of this paper is to answer these questions.

    Rivera-Batiz and Romer (1991a) and Dinopoulos and Segerstrom (1999) studied trade policy in a model with two perfectly symmetric countries that impose the same tariff rate on all imported goods. Rivera-Batiz and Romer(1991a) find that, compared with free trade, trade restrictions reduce the global rate of economic growth. Unlike Rivera-Batiz and Romer (1991a), Dinopoulos and Segerstrom (1999) supposed two factors (unskilled and skilled labor) that are used in both production and R&D activities and found that trade liberalization not only promotes technological change, it also increased wage inequality within countries.

    Segerstrom, Anat and Dinopoulos (1990) introduce a North-South trade model to analyze trade policy issues. In their North-South trade model, Northern firms conduct R&D activities to develop higher quality products. These products are initially discovered and produced by firms in the North (developed countries) and are exported to the South (developing countries). Northern firms that innovate receive patent protection for their products and earn monopoly profits until their patents expire. Then production shifts to the South where wages are lower and the products are exported back to the North. They study the steady state equilibrium effects of prohibitive tariffs designed to protect dying industries from competition with Southern firms. These tariffs lead to higher relative wages for Northern workers and a lower rate of innovation in the North. But their model has "scale effects", namely the property that the steady state rate of economic growth is an increasing function of population size. Jones (1995a) criticizes this scale effect property. A variety of endogenous growth models without scale effects have been developed by Jones (1995b), Kortum (1997), Segerstrom (1998), Young (1998) and Howitt (1999).

    Sergerstrom and Dinopoulos (2007) adopt an endogenous growth model without scale effects to develop a new North-South trade model. Nevertheless, they left the analysis of tariff imposition in this model as an open question. We extend the North-South trade model developed by Dinopoulos and Segerstrom (2007) by adding tariffs and subsidies and then analyze trade policy using tariffs. We analyze the steady state effects of tariff imposition. Specifically, we study how the tariff imposition and recycling of its tariff revenue (subsidy to domestic firms) of the North (a developed country) or the South (a developing country) affects the innovation rate in the North, imitation rate in the South, wage differential between the two regions, and long-run growth rate of the world economy. Like Dinopoulos and Segerstrom (2007), the innovation only occurs in the North and the South imitates the Northern products. In this paper, Northern firms devote their resources to innovative R&D that enables them to discover higher quality products and Southern firms also devote their resources to imitative R&D that enables them to copy the state-of-the-art quality products. We assume that each government uses its tariff revenue to subsidize domestic R&D. This assumption is based upon the fact that R&D expenditure financed by the government accounts for a substantial percentage in most countries; in particular, 58.6% in Poland, 44.4% in Hungary, and 50.2% in Mexico in 2007 (see Table A1).

    We consider the following three cases: first, a tariff imposition only in the South; second, a tariff imposition only in the North; and third, a tariff imposition in both regions. In the first case, we show that a tariff imposition in the South has no effect on the long run growth rate,2 but it leads to a temporary increase in the innovation rate and a permanent increase in the imitation rate. We also show that it reduces wage inequality between the North and the South and leads to higher utility for Southern consumers in the steady state. In the second case, we show that a tariff imposition in the North has no effect on the long-run growth rate, but it causes a temporary increase in the innovation rate and a permanent decrease in the imitation rate. We show that a tariff imposition in the North enlarges wage inequality between the North and the South and leads to higher utility for Northern consumers in the steady state. In the third case, we show that a tariff imposition in both regions temporarily raises the innovation rate, but does not change the long-run rate. The effects on the imitation rate and wage inequality have little effect on the simulation analysis. However, the steady state utility in both regions increased because of quality improvement. The long-run rate of technological change in our model is proportional to the exogenous rate of population growth, and therefore tariffs have no long-run effect, as in other models of economic growth without the scale effect by Jones (1995b) and Kortum (1997).

    The rest of the paper is organized as follows. In Section 2, we define our ynamic general equilibrium model of North-South trade with tariffs and subsidies. In Section 3, we identify the steady state conditions for the economy and state the main results. We conclude in Section 4.

    1The trade-weighted average tariff for all products of the United States in 2008 was 2%, with 4.1% for agricultural products and 1.9% for non-agricultural products. However, average tariffs vary by industry. In particular, average tariffs were 21.1% for dairy products and 11.4% for clothing. In the case of China, the weighted-average tariff for all products was 4.3%, with tariffs of 10.3% for agricultural products and 4.0% for non agricultural products. Average tariffs were 27.4% for sugars and confectionery and 16.1% for clothing.  2The long-run growth rate or the steady state innovation rate depends only on the population growth rate n and the R&D difficulty parameter λ, as in Segerstrom (1998). The steady state innovation rate is (n/(1-λ)) in this model.

    Ⅱ. The Model

    We add tariffs and subsidies to the model of Dinopoulos and Segerstrom (2007). Nevertheless, we will follow the same reasoning as in their paper to derive conditions for steady-state equilibrium.3 There are two regions in the world economy, the North (a developed country) and the South (a developing country). Innovation in the North and imitation in the South take place in the context of trade relations between the two regions. Workers in the North are capable of conducting both innovative and imitative R&D, but workers in the South can only conduct imitative R&D because of the insufficiency of highly trained and specialized labor. In the South, technological progress, or imitation, occurs through the import of product designs and production methods developed in the North.

       1. Industry Structure and Quality Improvement

    There is a continuum of industries indexed by θ∈[0,1] in both the North and the South. In all industries θ∈[0,1], a firm produces its product of a quality level j∈{0,1,2,...} which changes over time as follows: at time 0, the highest quality j=0, and at time t, the quality can reach the level j+1 if the highest quality at time t-1 is j and the firm invests in R&D activity.

       2. Consumers

    In both the North and the South, there is a fixed number of households at each time. Each member of a household lives forever and is endowed with one unit of labor. The size of each household grows exponentially at the fixed rate n>0. Thus, the number of consumers at time t is given by ent . At time zero, the North has

    image

    population and the South has

    image

    population. The North and the South have the same population growth rate n. Therefore at time t, the supply of labor in the North is

    image

    and the supply of labor in the South is

    image

    The total supply of labor in the North and the South combined at time t is

    image

    Consumers have identical preferences in the North and the South. Temporal preferences of consumers are given by

    image

    where d(j,θ,t) denotes the quality j consumption of product θ at time t, σ > 1 is the constant elasticity of substitution between products across industries, and δ >1 is the quality parameter. Because δj is increasing in j, consumers prefer the higher quality product.

    Lifetime utility is given by the discounted sum of the temporal utilities as follows:

    image

    where ρ > n is the constant subjective discount rate.

    Each consumer maximizes the lifetime utility by choosing quantities of demand of all types and all qualities. This problem is solved in three steps.

    The first step is to solve an industry wide static optimization problem for each industry θ and each time t,

    image
    image

    where p(j,θ,t) is the price of θ-good of quality j at time t, and c(θ,t) is the consumer's expenditure on θ-good at time t. The solution for this problem is to buy only the product with the lowest quality adjusted price pj (θ)/δj. Assume that when the two products have the same quality adjusted price, the consumer consumes the highest quality product.

    The second step is to solve the cross industry static optimization problem. For each t,

    image

    where j(θ,t) is the quality of θ-good chosen at time t (determined in the first step) and d(θ,t) is the quantity of demand for this good, and c(t) denotes the total expenditure at time t. Solving this problem yields the individual consumer's demand function as follows. Define a quality measure at time by q(θ,t) = δ(σ-1)j(θ,t). Note that since j(θ,t) does not depend on c(θ,t), then j(θ,t) does not depend on c(t) and so q(θ,t) does not depend on c(t).

    The optimal consumption of θ-good of quality j(θ,t) is given by

    image

    The total spending on θ-good at time t is given by

    image

    The third step is the inter-temporal expenditure choice problem. Formally:

    image

    where A(t) is the asset value at time t, w(t) is the wage rate, and r(t) is the market interest rate. The solution for this optimal control problem satisfies

    image

    Hence, in a steady state equilibrium, where the expenditure of an individual consumer, c(t), is constant over time, the market interest rate r is equal to the discount rate; that is, r(t) = p for each t.

       3. Production Technology and Market Structure

    Any firm can exit the industry at any time in the North and in the South. Northern firms enter an industry in the North by discovering higher quality products and Southern firms enter by imitating the state-of-the-art products.

    There is only one input good, labor, and production technologies of all industries are identical and linear in each region. Northern producers have higher labor productivity than Southern producers. Let h > 1 be the labor productivity in the North and 1, the labor productivity in the South. Then when labor markets are competitive in each region, the constant marginal cost of a Northern firm equals wN/h and the constant marginal cost of a Southern firm equals wS, where wN and wS are wage rates in the North and the South, respectively. Exporting a product from one region to another incurs a simple form of trade cost. In order to export 1 unit, the exporting firm should produce φ ≥ 1 units.

    There is an identical production technology across the North and the South, across products, and across quality levels. Goods are produced using one input good, labor, and their production technology exhibits constant returns to scale, f(l) = l. This means that one unit of labor produces one unit of output independent of its quality level or geographic location.

    Labor markets are segmented in the North and the South and are perfectly competitive in each region. The wage rate in the North is denoted by wN and wage rate of the South is denoted by wS. Each firm in the North has a constant marginal cost equal to wN and each firm in the South has a constant marginal cost equal to wS. We restrict our attention to the case when wN > wS > wN. The first part (wN > wS) implies that production shifts from the North to the South when a Southern firm imitates. The second (wS > wN) implies that the production shifts back to the North when a Northern firm innovates.

    Governments of the North and the South can impose tariffs on imported goods. The tariff rate of the Northern government is denoted by τN and the tariff rate of the Southern government is denoted by τS.

    In any industry, firms (the North or the South) producing different qualities are under the Bertrand price competition. In the case of drastic innovation, the new quality leader immediately charges the unconstrained monopoly price and in the case of non-drastic innovation, the new quality leader charges a limited price initially and immediately reverts to charging the unconstrained monopoly price when he learns that the previous quality leader exited the market. We assume a drastic innovation as in Segerstrom and Dinopoulos (2007).

    1) Price Determination of Northern Firms

    If a Northern firm wins the innovative R&D race, then given the ad-valorem tariff τS in the Southern market, its profit is given by

    where pN is the price of the Northern product in the North and p*N is the “post-tariff” price of the Northern product in the South, dN is the per capita Northern demand, dS, is the per capita Southern demand. The first part of the Northern firm's profit is from the Northern market and second part is from the Southern market.

    In the Northern market, since the price elasticity of demand for all θ is σ and marginal cost of Northern firms is wN/h, the monopoly mark-up price of Northern firms is

    image

    In the Southern market, since Northern firms have to pay a tariff to the foreign (Southern) government when they export the state-of-the-art product to the Southern market, they determine a "pre-tariff" price to maximize the "post-tariff" revenue. Then the Northern firm's profit maximization problem is given as follows: for any τS

    image

    where p is the price level and q is the quantity level. The first order condition is

    image

    This is the markup condition

    image

    where

    image

    is the price elasticity of demand. In this paper, consumers have a constant elasticity of demand ϵ = σ, and constant marginal cost is wN/h. So the "pre-tariff" price set by the Northern firm in the Southern market is

    image

    This “pre-tariff” price is the price which the Southern consumer actually confronts. Thus by (7), “post-tariff” price p*N equals pN.4 This “post-tariff” price is the price which the Northern firm actually confronts after the imposition of tariffs.

    2) Price Determination of Southern Fir

    If a Southern firm wins the imitative R&D race and the North imposes the ad-valorem tariff τN for the Southern product, its profit is given by

    where pS is the price set by the Southern firm in the Southern market, p*S is the "post-tariff" price set by the Southern firm in the Northern market.

    The Southern firm sets the monopoly price in the Southern market; that is,

    image

    And the “pre-tariff” price set by the Southern firm in the Northern market is

    image

    Thus by (9), the “post-tariff” price p*S equals to pS.5

    Before deriving an alternative expression for the value of the monopoly profit, we introduce some additional notation. Let cN(t) denote the consumption expenditure of the representative Northern consumer at time t and let cS(t) denote the consumption expenditure of the representative Southern consumer at time t. Then the global consumption expenditure is

    image

    Where

    image

    is the global per capita consumption expenditure. In the presence of tariffs, Northern consumers face different prices than Southern consumers and we need to take this into account. Let the Northern quality adjusted price index be defined by

    image

    and let the Southern price index be defined by

    image

    where stars denote exports, subscripts denote production location, is the set of industries with Northern production and is the set of industries with Southern production. Using (3), the Northern consumers demand for a domestically produced good is

    image

    The Northern consumer's demand for an imported good (exported by the South) is

    image

    The Southern consumer's demand for a domestically produced good is

    image

    And the Southern consumer's demand for an imported good (exported by the North) is

    image

    Additionally, we find the following relationship:

    image

    Using the above mentioned notation, a Northern quality leader in industry θ at time t earns the following monopoly profit: where

    image
    image

    If a Southern quality leader wins imitative R&D, then its profit is given by

    image
    image

       4. Innovative R&D and Imitative R&D

    Labor is the only factor of production used by firms that engage in either innovative or imitative R&D activities. When Northern firm i hires li labor for innovative R&D, its probability of success Ii (in discovering the next higher quality) is given by

    image

    where γ > 0 indicates the innovative R&D productivity parameter. Thus, as the quality improves, the probability of success goes down.6

    Southern firms use labor for imitative R&D. When Southern firm i hires li labor for imitative R&D, its probability of success of imitative R&D (imitating the state-of-the-art product in industry θ) is given by

    image

    where β > 0 is the imitative R&D productivity parameter. As the quality improves, the probability of success goes down. The level of β can also be interpreted as the degree of intellectual property rights enforcement.

    The returns to both innovative and imitative R&D's are assumed to be independently distributed across firms, across industries and across time. The probability that some Northern firms innovate in an industry is given by

    image

    The probability that some Southern firms imitate in an industry is given by

    image

    At time t, a measure of mN industries denotes Northern quality leaders, a measure of mS industries denotes Southern quality leaders, and their sum equals 1, that is

    image

    In the steady state, the flow into the industries must be in equal size to the flow out of the industries. If a Southern firm imitates a product of another Southern firm, the profits of both Southern firms become zero because they are involved in the Bertrand price competition. Hence Southern firms imitate the products of Northern firms. If a Southern firm successfully imitates a Northern product, then the production base shifts to the South.7 If a Northern firm successfully innovates a Northern product, this does not cause any shift in the product base. If a Northern firm successfully innovates a Southern product, the production base shifts to the North. Therefore, we obtain the following equation in the steady state.

    Using (19), we can derive mN and mS as a function of the innovation rate and the imitation rate as follows

    image

       5. R&D Optimization

    All firms maximize expected discounted profits and there is free entry to innovative R&D races in the North. Since all firms have the same innovative R&D technology, a Northern quality leader does not engage in R&D activities. Other firms except the Northern quality leader have incentives to engage themselves in innovative R&D races.

    In the steady state, the expected benefit from the innovative R&D is equal to the expected cost. And we assume that the government revenue from the Northern tariff is used to subsidize Northern firms. Let υI(θ,t) be the expected discounted profit from innovative R&D and sI(τN) the innovative R&D subsidy rate in the North. The subsidy rate depends on τN and

    image

    Firm i’s probability of successful innovation during time interval dt is measured by Iidt. Therefore, the expected benefit from innovative R&D is given by υI(θ,t)Iidt. Expected cost from the innovative R&D during interval dt is (1 – sI(τN))wnIidt, which equals (1 – sI(τN)) wnγq(θ,t)Iidt by (17).

    Thus, we obtain the following steady state R&D optimization condition:

    image

    There is also free entry into all imitative R&D races in the South. In the steady state, the expected benefit from the imitative R&D will be equal to the expected cost. Let υc(θ,t) be the expected discounted profits for imitative R&D and sC(τS) the imitative R&D subsidy rate in the South. The subsidy rate depends on the Southern tariff rate and

    image

    Firm i's probability of successful imitation during the time interval dt is Cidt. Thus the expected benefit from imitative R&D is υC(θ,t)Cidt. Likewise, the expected cost from imitative R&D is (1 – sC(τS))wCIidt which equals (1 – sC(τS))wSβq(θ,t)Cidtby (18). Thus, the steady state R&D optimization condition of the Southern firm under the free entry condition is given by

    image

       6. The Stock Market

    1) Northern Firms

    In the stock market, households diversify the risk of holding stocks issued by Northern and Southern firms. Through the no-arbitrage condition, the return from holding the stock of a Northern quality leader must be the same as the return from an equal sized investment in a riskless bond; that is

    image

    where

    image

    is the dividend rate from the stock of a Northern quality leader,

    image

    is the capital gains rate. By the consumer optimization condition, the market interest rate r equals the subjective discount rate p in the steady state. Since υI(θ,t) is constant in the steady state,8 the steady state equilibrium reward from innovative R&D is given by

    image

    2) Southern Firms

    The stock market value of the Southern quality leader can be similarly derived. The return from holding the stock of a Southern quality leader must be the same as the return from an equal sized investment in a riskless bond. Then, the corresponding no arbitrage condition is

    image

    where

    image

    is the dividend rate from the stock and

    image

    is the capital gains rate. The profits of the Southern quality leader are discounted by the market interest rate. The Southern firm has a possibility to lose its business (i.e. exit the industry) by probability I. The steady state equilibrium reward from imitative R&D is given by

    image

       7. Steady State R&D Conditions

    1) Northern Firms

    Using (21) and (24), we get

    image

    Substituting πN of (15) into (27) and using the above notation, we rewrite the steady state R&D condition as follows.

    image

    The left hand side of (28) is related with the benefit of innovative R&D. The benefit is increasing in cN and cS, which means that average consumer buys more as yN(t) or y*N(t) increase. It is also increasing in initial population capacities

    image

    However, the benefit decreases when discount rate ρ, imitation rate of Southern firms C, or innovation rate of Northern firms I increases. If the tariff rate of the South, τS, increases, the benefit of innovative R&D decreases. The cost of innovating increases when γ increases (innovating becomes more difficult), but it decreases as the R&D subsidy rate sIN)increases.

    2) Southern Firms

    Using (22) and (26), we get

    image

    Substituting πS of (16) into the (29) and using the above notation, we rewrite the steady state R&D condition as follows.

    image

    The left hand side of (30) is related with the benefit of imitative R&D. The benefit is increasing in cN and cS. It is also increasing in initial population capacities

    image

    However, the benefit decreases when the future discount rate ρ or the innovation rate of Northern firms I increases. And the benefit of imitative R&D is decreasing in Northern tariffs τN. The right hand side is related to the cost of imitative R&D. The cost increases as the level of β increases, but it decreases as the R&D subsidy rate sCS) increases.

       8. Quality Dynamics

    The average quality of products at time t is given by

    image

    where λ = δ(σ–1) > 1. When innovation occurs in industry θ, the quality improves from λJ(θ,t) to λJ(θ,t) + 1. Since the innovation rate I is constant across industries and over time, the quality improvement rate during time interval is given by

    image

    From this equation,

    image

    Since the level of relative R&D difficulty xN = Q(t)/LN(t) is constant over time and the population growth rate is n, the long-run steady state innovation rate is given by

    image

    Note that the long-run steady state innovation rate does not depend on the tariff rate, even if the innovation level depends on the tariff rate.

    The average quality of all products can be decomposed into the average quality of the Northern leading firms and the average quality of the Southern leading firms as follows:

    image

    where QN(t) is the measure of product quality of the Northern firms, and QS(t) is the measure of product quality of the Southern firms. The two quality measures QN(t) and QS(t) evolve over time in the steady state equilibrium. The quality of the Southern leading firms improves after successful imitations and decreases after successful innovations by Northern firms. Then the time derivative of QS(t) is given by

    image

    The quality of the Northern leading firms improves after successful innovations, but decreases after successful imitations. Then the time derivative of QN(t) is given by

    image

    The growth rates of QN(t) and QS(t) in the steady state are identical. Therefore, using (35) and (36), we obtain

    image
    image

       9. Labor Markets

    1) The Northern Labor Market

    We assume that workers can move freely and instantaneously across firms in the North and the South. In each region, we assume the full employment condition and wage rate is determined by supply and demand in each labor market. The Northern labor demand is composed of two parts, manufacturing employment and R&D employment. Since one unit of product requires one unit of labor, the labor requirement of Northern manufacturing companies equals the world demand for Northern products. Thus the production employment in Northern industry θ is given by

    image

    Since there are leading industries in the North, the total manufacturing labor demand by Northern firms is given by

    image

    Northern R&D employment of industry θ at time t is Σili = γIq(θ,t). Therefore, the total Northern R&D employment is given by

    image

    The labor supply of the North in time t is LN(t). From (40) and (41), the full employment condition in the North is

    image

    The Northern manufacturing labor demand increases as YN (demand for Northern products by average consumers) increases and

    image

    (the ratio of Northern products) increases, but decreases as the Southern tariff rate increases. The Northern R&D labor demand is increasing in innovation rare I and innovative R&D difficulty xN.

    2) The Southern Labor Market

    Similarly, manufacturing employment in Southern industry θ is given by

    image

    The total manufacturing employment in the South is given by

    image

    Since the Southern R&D employment in industry θ at time t is Σili = βCIq(θ,t), total Southern R&D employment is

    image

    And the labor supply of the South at time t is LS(t). From (44) and (45), the full employment condition in the South is given by

    image

    The Southern manufacturing labor demand increases as YS (demand for Southern products by average consumers) increases and

    image

    (the ratio of Northern product) increases, but decreases as the Northern tariff increases.

    3Specifically, sections 2.1, 2.2, 2.4 follow the same equations as Segerstrom and Dinopoulos (2007).  4.  5.  6This application removes the scale effect of the growth theory criticized by Jones (1995).  7This is called Vernon (1966)’s product cycle model.  8In the steady state condition,

    Ⅲ. The Steady State Equilibrium

       1. Existence of the Steady State Condition

    We determine the Northern steady state condition from the equations (28), (42) and xN = Q(t)/LN(t).

    image

    Similarly, the Southern steady state condition from the equations (30), (46) and xN = Q(t)/LN(t) yields the following equation

    image

    Note that tariff imposition in the South does not affect the Northern steady state condition. It only affects the Southern steady state condition through the subsidy for Southern firms. Also note that tariff imposition in the North does not affect the Southern steady state condition. It only affects the Northern steady state condition through the subsidy for Northern firms.

    From the two steady state conditions in the two regions, we identify the imitation rate C, the short-run innovation rate in the steady state, and the time path of Q(t) using

    image

    Thus the quality improves (technology progress) faster as the short-run innovation rate gets higher.

    To get the formula for the steady state wage differential w = wN/wS, we use (28) and (30) to get

    image

    Using (11), (13),

    image

    Thus from (50), we can derive the following wage differential equation:

    image

    This wage differential equation implies that the North-South wage gap w is indirectly related to the change in tariffs through the change of (ρ + I)/(ρ + I + C), which is the reward for innovative R&D relative to the reward for imitative R&D. Clearly, it is also directly related to tariffs, τN and τS.

       2. Effects of Tariffs

    To analyze the effects of a tariff imposition, we compare the equilibrium without a tariff with the equilibrium in the following three cases: first, when only the South imposes a tariff; second, when only the North imposes a tariff; and third, when both regions impose tariffs. From (47) and (48), we obtain the following steady state conditions without a tariff:

    image
    image

    1) Effects of Tariff Imposition in the South

    Assume, that there is no tariff in the North and that the South imposes tariff τS on imported Northern state-of-the-art products. Assume that the Southern tariff revenue subsidizes domestic imitative R&D. Recall that the tariff imposition does not change the Northern steady state condition and so (52) prevails in the North. The Southern steady state condition shifts from (53) to (48) (see Figure 2).

    In Figure 2, the steady state equilibrium without a tariff is denoted by E. After tariff imposition in the South, the decreasing curve indicating the Southern steady state condition shifts to the right. Thus we obtain the new steady state equilibrium at E*, which has the higher short-run innovation rate xN and the higher imitation rate C. It follows from (49) that the average quality of products Q improves as xN increases. And it follows from (20) that the ratio of the Southern quality leader mS increases and the ratio of the Northern quality leader mN decreases as C increases. This means that more industries shift from the North to the South. It follows from (51) that wage differential w decreases as both C and τS increase. It should be noted that all these effects are due to Southern imitative R&D subsidies financed by tariff revenue. As is clear from (48), if the tariff revenue is not used for subsidizing domestic R&D, there is no steady state effect of Southern tariff imposition. Therefore, we obtain the following result.

    Proposition 1 If the South imposes a tariff on Northern innovative products, then it leads to a higher imitation rate and a higher short-run innovation rate (C↑ and xN↑) and the steady state relative wage decreases (w↓), the long-run innovation rate (I=(n/(λ-1))) does not change, and industries shift from the North to the South (mN↓, mS↑).

    The steady state of Southern tariff imposition is quite intuitive. The subsidy to the Southern firm from tariff revenue makes imitation R&D more efficient. This leads to more imitation in the South and more industries will move from the North to the South (mN↓, mS↑).

    The profit of Northern firm (πN) will decrease caused by the decrease in demand (See 15). The decrease of the profit of Northern firms reduces the R&D benefit of innovation (R&D Reducing Effect) (See 28). On the other hand, the decrease of demand in Northern products leads to a decrease in labor demand in the manufacturing sector in the North (See 39). More Northern workers become available for employment in the Northern R&D sector which makes it more attractive for Northern firms to expand their R&D activities (R&D Enhancing Effect). These two effects offset the Northern steady state equilibrium.

    But the industry shift from the North to the South because of the Southern subsidy makes more R&D labor available in the North. Therefore, the short-run innovation rate will jump and technological change will accelerate, but the industry level innovation rate will gradually fall back to the original steady state level I = n/(λ – 1), as R&D becomes relatively more difficult.

    2) Effects of Tariff Imposition in the North

    Assume that there is no tariff in the South and that the North imposes tariff τN on imported Southern products. Assume that the Northern tariff revenue subsidizes domestic innovative R&D. Recall that the tariff imposition does not change the Southern steady state condition and so (53) prevails in the South. The Northern steady state condition shifts from (52) to (47) (see Figure 3).

    After the Northern tariff imposition, the Northern steady state condition curve shifts to the right and the original steady state equilibrium E moves down to a new steady state equilibrium E* in Figure 3. Therefore, the short-run innovation rate xN increases, but imitation rate C decreases. From (49), the average quality of products Q improves. From (20), the ratio of the Southern quality leader mS decreases and the ratio of the Northern quality leader mN increases. This means that more industries shift from the South to the North. From (51), wage differential w increases. Therefore, we obtain the following result.

    Proposition 2 If the North imposes tariffs on Southern imitative products, then the imitation rate decreases (C↓), the short-run innovation rate increases (xN ↑), the steady state relative wage increases (w↑), the long-run innovation rate (I=(n/(λ-1))) does not change, and industries shift from the South to the North (↑,↓).

    The steady state of Northern tariff imposition is also intuitive. The subsidy to the Northern firm from tariff revenue makes innovation R&D more efficient. This leads to more innovation R&D in the North. Therefore, the short-run innovation rate will jump and technological change to accelerate, but the industry level innovation rate will gradually fall back to the original steady state level I = n/(λ – 1) as R&D becomes relatively more difficult.

    The profit of Southern firm πS will decrease because of the decrease in demand (See 16). The decrease of the profit of Southern firms reduces the R&D benefit of imitation (R&D Reducing Effect) (See 30). So the imitation rate (C ↓) will decrease. Therefore, more industry will move from the South to the North (mN↓, mS↑)

    On the other hand, the more industry shifts from the South to the North, there will be a decrease in labor demand in the manufacturing sector in the South (See 43). More Southern workers become available for employment in the Southern R&D sector. This makes it more attractive for Southern firms to expand their R&D activities (R&D Enhancing Effect). These two effects offset the Southern steady state equilibrium.

    3) Effects of Simultaneous Tariff Imposition in the North and in the South

    Now assume that both the North and the South impose tariffs on imported goods and subsidize their domestic R&D programs. At that time, both the Northern steady state condition and the Southern steady state condition will change to (47) and (48) (see Figure 4).

    In this case, both the Northern steady state curve and the Southern steady state curve shift to the right. The original steady state equilibrium E moves to a new steady state equilibrium E* as depicted in Figure 4. The short-run innovation rate increases, but the effects on the imitation rate of the South and wage differential are not determined analytically. However, we expect there will be no big change in the imitation rate of the South or wage differential. The welfare of both regions can not be analytically determined. Therefore, these questions need numerical analysis. Eventually, we obtain the following proposition.

    Proposition 3 If both the North and the South impose tariffs, then the short-run innovation rate increases and the long-run innovation rate (I=n/(λ-1)) does not change.

       3. Steady State Utility Paths

    Let VN denote the total market value of all Northern firms at t = 0 and let VS denote the total market value of all Southern firms at t = 0. To solve the model, these market values are in the steady state equilibrium.

    First, consider how the price indices evolve over time. Using (37), we obtain that

    image

    Thus the Northern price index PN(t) decreases over time with product quality Q(t) and increases with the Northern tariff rate τN. The same holds for the Southern price index,

    image

    Thus the Southern price index PS(t) decreases with product quality Q(t) and increases with the Southern tariff rate τS.

    During the lifetime of the firm, q(θ,t) is constant, pN = wN/αh is constant since wN is constant, PN(t)1 – σ/ Q(t) and PS(t)1 – σ/ Q(t) are constants, and Q(t)/Q(t) = (λ – 1)I = n, so LN(t)PN(t)1 – σ and LS(t)PS(t)1 – σ are also constants over time. So the firm's profit flow πN(θ,t) is also constant over time. Consequently, the market value of a Northern firm does not change over the course of the firm's lifetime. Using this information,

    image

    Substituting using (35) and

    image

    we determine that the market value of all Northern firms at t=0 is

    image

    Using similar notations, the market value of all Southern firms at t = 0 is

    image

    Other things being equal, the market value of firms in a region is higher when workers earn higher wages and when innovating is relatively more difficult.

    Having determined the market value of the firms, let's solve for consumer expenditures. Let AN(t) and AS(t) denote the financial assets of the representative Northern consumer and Southern consumer. Assume that Northern consumers own the Northern firms and Southern consumers own the Southern firms, that is, AN(t) = VN(t)/LN(t) and AS(t) = VS(t)/LS(t).The inter-temporal budget constraint of the representative Northern consumer AN(t) = wN + ρAN(t) – cNnAN(t) can be rewritten as

    image

    since the growth rate of AN(t) must be constant over time in any steady state equilibrium. The inter-temporal budget constraint implies that AN must be constant over time in any steady state equilibrium. Using (56), the representative Northern consumer's expenditure at steady state is

    image

    The representative Northern consumer's expenditure is wage income plus interest income on financial assets appropriately adjusted to take into account the splitting of the financial assets that result from population growth. Using (57), the representative Northern consumer's expenditure at the steady state is

    image

    We now turn to the steady state utility paths of representative consumers in the North and South, respectively. For the typical Northern consumer, the utility at time t is

    image

    Substituting (11) and (12) yields

    image

    From (58) and (54), the steady state utility of the North is

    image

    and the corresponding calculations for the Southern consumer yields

    image

    From (59) and (55), the steady state utility of the South is

    image

    As Dinoupoulos and Segerstrom (2007) identified that, since the old new steady state equilibrium paths involve the same rate of economic growth, we can compare utility levels at time t = 0 in the old and new steady states to determine whether the change makes consumers better off in the long run.

    Ⅳ. Simulation Analysis

    The results of the simulation analysis should be interpreted as suggestive rather than conclusive, but these results give some implications on the problems which could not be solved analytically. We supposed that the following benchmark parameter values as in Dinopoulos and Segerstrom (2007) were ρ = 0.07, n = 0.014

    image

    σ = 1.5 and h = 1.67. Additionally λ = δ(σ–1) = 1.3. The results from the computer simulations are reported in Table 1 and the first column shows the endogenous variables for the benchmark parameter values. The second column shows the changes of endogenous variables in the case of a tariff imposition in the South. We supposed the Southern tariff rate is 10% and this tariff revenue was used to subsidize R&D. For analytical simplicity, I supposed that a 10% increase in the tariff rate comes down to the 10% reduction of labor cost. i.e. we supposed that the labor productivity will increase 10% because of the improved productivity due to the subsidy of R&D. The third column shows the changes of the endogenous variables in the case of a tariff imposition in the North. I also supposed that a 10% increase in the Northern tariff rate comes down to the 10% reduction of labor cost. The fourth column shows the changes of the endogenous variables in the case of a tariff imposition in both regions. We supposed that the tariff rate is 10% in both regions and these tariff revenues were used to subsidize R&D in each region.

    First, the results confirm proposition 1. According to a tariff imposition in the South, C increased from 0.048534 to 0.055627 and xN slightly increased from 10.804 to 10.87. Also the industry moved from the North to the South. The share of the Northern products (mN) decreased from 0.49019 to 0.46999 and the share of the Southern products (mS) increased from 0.50981 to 0.53001. The relative wage (w) decreased from 2.1689 to 1.8909. The steady state welfare of the Northern consumers decreased (uN(0) fell from 3.9094 to 3.8320) and the steady state welfare of the Southern consumers increased (uS(0) rose from 3.5457 to 3.6343).

    Second, the results confirm proposition 2. According to a tariff imposition in the North, C slightly decreased from 0.048534 to 0.044802 and xN increased from 10.804 to 11.304. The industry moved from the South to the North. The share of the Northern products (mN) increased from 0.49019 to 0.51019 and the share of the Southern products (mS) decreased from 0.50981 to 0.48981. The relative wage (w) increased from 2.1689 to 2.4851. The steady state welfare of the Northern consumers increased (uN(0) rose from 3.9094 to 4.0917) and the steady state welfare of the Southern consumers slightly increased (uS(0) rose from 3.5457 to 3.5568). Even through the Southern consumers confront a higher price for the imported Northern products due to the tariff, the Southern consumers receive a higher quality of imported Northern products. So the overall steady state utility of the Southern consumers slightly increased.

    Third, the results confirm proposition 3 and show more clearly the undetermined effects. According to a tariff imposition in both regions, C remains almost the same as the benchmark solution, but xN greatly increased from 10.804 to 11.367. The tariff imposition in both regions had little effect on the proportion of the industry in each region. It also had little effect on the relative wage (w slightly changed from 2.1689 to 2.1693). The steady state welfare of the Northern consumers increased (uN(0) rose from 3.9094 to 4.013) and the steady state welfare of the Southern consumers slightly increased (uS(0) rose from 3.5457 to 3.6466). As such, it is because the effect of quality improvement exceeded the effect of the rising prices of imported goods in both regions.

    [Table 1] The Result of Computer Simulations

    label

    The Result of Computer Simulations

    Ⅴ. Concluding Remarks

    We adopted a dynamic general equilibrium model of North-South trade with scale invariant growth developed by Segerstrom and Dinopoulos (2007) to analyze the steady state effects of tariff imposition. We consider the effects of a tariff starting from a situation of free trade. Assuming that each government uses tariff revenue to subsidize domestic R&D, we showed that tariff imposition in the South leads to more copying of Northern products, faster technological change, lower wage inequality between the North and the South and higher welfare for the Southern consumers. Tariff imposition in the North leads to less copying of Northern products, faster technological change, higher wage inequality between the North and the South and higher welfare for the Northern consumers. Tariff imposition, both in the North and the South, leads to faster technological change and higher welfare in both regions, but has little effect on imitation rate and wage differentials.

참고문헌
  • 1. Aghion P., Howitt P. (1992) “A Model of Growth through Creative Destruction” [Econometrica] Vol.60 P.323-51 google cross ref
  • 2. Aghion P., Howitt P. (1998) Endogenous Growth Theory google
  • 3. Bhagwati J. N., Panagariya A., Srinivasan T.N. (1998) “Endogenous Growth Innovation and Trade,” Lectures on International Trade P.527-540 google
  • 4. Brock P. L., Turnovsky S. (1993) “The growth and welfare consequences of differ ential tariffs” [International Economic Review] Vol.34 P.765-794 google cross ref
  • 5. Dinopoulos E., Segerstrom P. S. (1999) “The Dynamic effects and Contingent Tariffs” [Journal of International Economics] Vol.47 P.191-222 google cross ref
  • 6. Dinopoulos E., Segerstrom P. S. (2007) “North-South Trade and Economic Growth,” Working Paper google
  • 7. Dinopoulos E., Segerstrom P. S. (2010) “Intellectual Property Rights, Multinational Firms and Economic Growth” [Journal of Development Economics] Vol.92 P.13-27 google cross ref
  • 8. Dinopoulos E., Syropoulos C. (1997) “Tariffs and Schumpeterian Growth” [Journal of International Economics] Vol.42 P.425-452 google cross ref
  • 9. Dinopoulos E., Paul S. Segerstrom (1999) “A Schumpeterian Model of Protection and Relative Wages” [American Economic Review] Vol.89 P.450-472 google cross ref
  • 10. Dinopoulos E., Thompson P. (1998) “Schumpeterian Growth without Scale Effects” [Journal of Economic Growth] Vol.3 P.313-335 google cross ref
  • 11. Dinopoulos E., Thompson P. (2010) “Intellectual Property Rights, Multinational Firms and Economic Growth” [Journal of Development Economics] Vol.92 P.13-27 google cross ref
  • 12. Dixit A., Stiglitz J. E. (1997) “Monopolistic Competition and Optimum Product Diversity” [American Economic Review] Vol.67 P.297-308 google
  • 13. Galor O. (1994) “Tariffs, income distribution and welfare in a small overlapping generations economy” [International Economic Review] Vol.35 P.173-192 google cross ref
  • 14. Grossman G. M., Helpman E. (1991) Innovation and Growth in the Global Economy google
  • 15. Grossman G. M., Helpman E. (1991a) “Growth welfare in a small open economy,” International Trade and Trade Policy P.141-163 google
  • 16. Grossman G. M., Helpman E. (1991b) “Quality Ladders and Product Cycles” [Quarterly Journal of Economics] Vol.106 P.557-558 google cross ref
  • 17. Grossman G. M., Helpman E. (1991c) “Endogenous Product Cycles” [The Economic Journal] Vol.101 P.1214-1229 google cross ref
  • 18. Grossman G. M., Helpman E. (1994) “Endogenous Innovation in the Theory of Growth” [Journal of Economic Perspectives] Vol.8 P.23-44 google cross ref
  • 19. Gustafsson P., Segerstrom P. S. (2010a) “North-South Trade with Multinational Firms and Increasing Product Variety,” International Economic Review, forthcoming google
  • 20. Gustafsson P., Segerstrom P. S. (2010b) “North-South Trade with Increasing Product Variety” [Journal of Development Economics] Vol.92 P.97-106 google cross ref
  • 21. Howitt P. (1999) “Steady Endogenous Growth with Population and R&D Inputs Growing” [Journal of Political Economy] P.715-730 google cross ref
  • 22. Jones C. (1995a) “Time Series Tests of Endogenous Growth Models” [Quarterly Journal of Economics] Vol.110 P.495-525 google cross ref
  • 23. Jones C. (1995b) “R&D-Based Models of Economic Growth” [Journal of Political Economy] Vol.103 P.759-784 google cross ref
  • 24. Kortum S. (1997) “Research, Patenting and Technological Change” [Econometrica] Vol.65 P.1389-1419 google cross ref
  • 25. Krugman P. (1979) “A Model of Innovation, Technology Transfer, and the World Distribution of Income” [Journal of Political Economy] Vol.87 P.253-266 google cross ref
  • 26. Lai E. (1998) “Intellectual Property Rights Protection and the Rate of Product Innovation” [Journal of Development Economics] Vol.55 P.133-153 google cross ref
  • 27. Li C. (2003) “Endogenous Growth without Scale Effects: Comment” [American Economic Review] Vol.93 P.1009-1017 google cross ref
  • 28. Long N. V.,, Wong K. (1997) “Endogenous Growth and International Trade: A Survey,” Dynamics, Economic Growth and International Trade google
  • 29. Mansfield E., Schwartz M., Wagner S. (1981) “Imitation Costs and Patents: An Empirical Study” [The Economic Journal] Vol.91 P.907-918 google cross ref
  • 30. Osang T., Periera A. (1996) “Import Tariffs and Growth in Small Open Economy” [Journal of Public Economics] Vol.60 P.45-71 google cross ref
  • 31. Rivera-Batiz L., Romer P. (1991a), “International trade with endogenous technological change” [European Economic Review] Vol.35 P.971-1004 google cross ref
  • 32. Rivera-Batiz L., Romer P. (1991b) “Economic Integration and Endogenous Growth” [Quarterly Journal of Economics] Vol.106 P.531-555 google cross ref
  • 33. Romer P. (1986) “Increasing Returns and Long Run Growth” [Journal of Political Economy] Vol.94 P.1002-1037 google cross ref
  • 34. Romer P. (1990) “Endogenous Technological Change” [Journal of Political Economy] Vol.98 P.S71-S102 google cross ref
  • 35. Schumpter J. A. (1942) Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy google
  • 36. Segerstrom P. (1991) “Innovation, Imitation, and Economic Growth” [Journal of Political Economy] Vol.99 P.807-827 google cross ref
  • 37. Segerstrom P. (1998) “Endogenous Growth without Scale Effects” [American Economic Review] Vol.88 P.1290-1310 google
  • 38. Segerstrom P., Anant T, Dinopoulos E (1990) “Schumpeterian Model of the Product Life Cycle” [American Economic Review] Vol.80 P.1077-1092 google
  • 39. Kim Suyi (2010) “A Theory of North South Trade and Foreign Direct Investment” [The Korean Economic Review] Vol.26 P.477-510 google
  • 40. Vernon R. (1966) “International Investment and International Trade in the Product Cycle” [Quarterly Journal of Economics] Vol.80 P.190-207 google cross ref
  • 41. Young A. (1998) “Growth without Scale Effects” [Journal of Political Economy] Vol.106 P.41-63 google cross ref
  • 42. (2010) World Tariff Profiles 2010 google
OAK XML 통계
이미지 / 테이블
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ Figure 1 ]  World Market Structure
    World Market Structure
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ Figure 2 ]  The Steady State Effects of a Southern tariff and Southern R&D Subsidy
    The Steady State Effects of a Southern tariff and Southern R&D Subsidy
  • [ Figure 3 ]  The Steady State Effects of a Northern Tariff Imposition.
    The Steady State Effects of a Northern Tariff Imposition.
  • [ Figure 4 ]  The Steady State Effects of Northern Tariff and Southern Tariff with Subsidies.
    The Steady State Effects of Northern Tariff and Southern Tariff with Subsidies.
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ Table 1 ]  The Result of Computer Simulations
    The Result of Computer Simulations
(우)06579 서울시 서초구 반포대로 201(반포동)
Tel. 02-537-6389 | Fax. 02-590-0571 | 문의 : oak2014@korea.kr
Copyright(c) National Library of Korea. All rights reserved.