검색 전체 메뉴
PDF
맨 위로
OA 학술지
Corporate Tax Incentives for R&D Investment in OECD Countries
ABSTRACT
Corporate Tax Incentives for R&D Investment in OECD Countries
KEYWORD
Corporate tax incentives , R&D investment , financial structure , net present value , OECD countries
  • 1. Introduction

    It is generally acknowledged that economic growth is driven by the accumulation of knowledge-based factors of production such as human capital, R&D and innovation. Moreover, such knowledge-based production factors determine a nation’s long-term competitiveness in a global world (Grossman & Helpman, 1991). In this context, the so-called endogenous growth theory argues that technological advancement is particularly stimulated by R&D activities of profit-maximizing firms (Romer, 1994). R&D enters the production process as a factor of production and is used in conjunction with other inputs. On the other hand, as with any investment decision, R&D is not undertaken unless there is an opportunity for profit.

    In many OECD countries specific tax incentives aimed at stimulating firms’ R&D investment activities have traditionally been kept (and even expanded) as an important measure of technology and innovation policy, although the majority of developed countries have carried out a series of ‘tax-rate-cut-cumbase-broadening’ corporate tax reforms in last two decades.1 This fact suggests that there has also been a sort of tax competition among the OECD countries regarding R&D promotion. In addition, the finding that social rates of return to R&D are substantially above private rates of return provides one of the main justifications for such government subsidies to R&D. Many believe that the lower private rates of return than the social rates cause the under-investment in R&D (Griffith, 2000). Furthermore, a tax-base subsidy appears to be the marketoriented response, since it leaves the choice of how to conduct and pursue the R&D programs in the hands of the private sector (Hall & van Reenen, 2000).

    Another attractive feature of these instruments is that tax incentives can be more predictable and accessible for businesses than direct subsidies. A possible drawback of fiscal instruments is that firms will not concentrate on projects with a high social rate of return. An additional shortcoming was believed to be ‘that fiscal incentives are simply ineffective in raising private R&D spending – the response elasticity is so low it would take a huge tax change to generate the socially desirable level of spending. This [used to be] the conventional wisdom […]’ (Hall & van Reenen, 2000, p. 449). Such theoretical considerations for the preferential tax treatment of R&D investment are supported by a large number of previous empirical investigations, which suggest its positive impact on firms’ R&D spending in many OECD countries (see Table 1).

    Compared with the case with usual fixed capital investment, financing constraints seem to apply more seriously to R&D investments (Bagella et al., 2001; Ughetto, 2008). Apart from the capital market imperfection leading to information asymmetry between lenders and borrowerswhen financing R&D investments (Hubbard, 1998), the limited availability of providing collateral to secure firm’s borrowing and the relatively high risk as well as the complex evaluation related to the future success of innovation activities make equity finance more attractive than debt finance. In particular, internally generated cash flow popularly applied for financing R&D investments in advanced economies has several advantages over debt including: (a) no collateral requirements, (b) avoidance of adverse selection problems, and (c) the limited scope of financial distress (Carpenter & Petersen, 2002; Brown et al., 2007). On the other hand, a strong reliance on internal equity can hinder the realisation of profitable and socially-desirable R&D opportunities of young and fast-growing innovative firms that require a higher sum of financial means than their internal cash flow obtained from existing profits. In addition, a smooth R&D investment path over time tends to be desirable. Yet the profit volatility caused by business cycle fluctuation may create an uncertainty in yielding necessary internal financial means required for R&D investments (Ughetto, 2008).

    [Table 1.] Positive effects of R&D-specific tax incentives revealed by selected empirical investigations

    label

    Positive effects of R&D-specific tax incentives revealed by selected empirical investigations

    As a large number of studies have already shown, the tax system is acknowledged as:

    Under the clear distinction between internal equity and debt finance, this study examines the generosity of various types of corporate tax incentives implemented in OECD countries to promote firms’ R&D investments on the basis of a net present value (NPV) model – a popular ‘forward-looking’ dynamic investment decision model.2 In other words, this study deals with a narrow scope of aspects related to corporate profit taxation and argues that discrete R&D investment decisions of profit maximising firms are dependent on the post-tax NPV. As with manyother previous research outcomes this study also confirmsthat the corporate tax system favours debt finance, since by a given tax depreciation scheme the absolute amount of after-tax NPV with debt finance is larger than that with internal equity finance. However, the explanation for the reasons is not only limited to the conventional, sole argument that corporate interest payments are deductible from the tax base, which in turn create extra tax savings. With debt finance, annual gross profits are also reduced by the amount of interest payments, from which the entire corporate tax burden is subtracted to calculate the posttax profits.3 Moreover, other than the case of financing investment cost by firms’ internal equity, the present value of debt-financed investment cost which is taken into accountwhen computing the after-taxNPVbecomes lower, since discounting (with the real interest rate) takes place for the repayment of the entire debt sum at the end of the given maturity years. The compound effect of all these features determines the superiority of debt finance. Yet, the preponderance of internal equity finance for R&D investment appears to be hardly explained in relation to the corporate tax incentive system, because the additional promotion effects (also expressed in terms of the post-tax NPV) of generous R&D-specific tax incentives over the normal depreciation rules (allowed for usual fixed capital investments) in the individual OECD countries remain the same, regardless of the different types of financial coverage of investment costs. Furthermore, with tax allowances and tax credits leading to the greatest R&D investment promotion effects in OECD countries, the after-tax NPV ceteris paribus increases with the corporate tax rate. This fact, in turn, suggests the possibility of stronger R&D investment promotion by adopting a sort of ‘tax-rate-increase-cum-base-broadening’ policy, a rather different tax policy option from the dominating tax-rate-cut-cum-basebroadening idea widely implemented in OECD countries.

    The structure of this paper is as follows. Section 2 explains the current R&D-oriented tax incentive systems in the OECD countries. After revisiting the Modigliani-Miller theorem of capital structure irrelevance, the third section technically describes the major nature of the present value model applied for the calculation of R&D investment promotion effects of the aforementioned tax policy measures. Section 4 illustrates the empirical results based on the calculated after-tax NPV under the plausible parameter assumptions and compares the international competitive position of individual countries led by the different R&D-promoting tax schemes. The final section summarises the major findings of the study and concludes.

    1The lower corporate tax rate tends to increase the incentive to invest, while the lower allowance is likely to decrease it. Therefore, the combined effect appears to depend on the details of each tax-rate-cut-cum-base-broadening reformin the individual OECD countries (Devereux et al., 2002).   2The superior features of NPV over the calculation of effective (marginal and average) corporate tax rates (King & Fullerton, 1984; Devereux & Griffith, 2003; Sørensen, 2004; Devereux, 2004) include, for example, that (i) the development of gross return generated by an investment can be more adequately considered, (ii) the true economic depreciation rate is not assumed but endogenously derived from the trend of gross return, and (iii) firms most widely apply this method in practice, especially when carrying out the so-called feasibility study for checking overall profitability of investment projects (see also Nam & Radulescu, 2007).   3Consequently this leads to the reduction of the after-tax NPV.

    2. Current Tax Treatment of R&D Investment in OECD Countries

    The statutory corporate tax rate is certainly important in determining the overall profit tax burden. However, this tax rate does not, in itself, establish the ultimate tax burden on a firms’ R&D investment activity. Equally crucial are the effects of depreciation and other investment promotion schemes that determine the tax base (Sørensen, 2004). In the practice of corporate tax policy, different tax depreciation rules are employed that do not typically ensure the true economic depreciation (Samuelson, 1964). Furthermore, their generosity has been extended to stimulate R&D investment activity of a firm. Similarly, the R&D tax allowances provide an additional deduction from taxable income of a firm, which indirectly lowers the amount of tax owed. In addition, the R&D tax credits are more widely applied in OECD countries that allow a deduction from the tax a firm must pay to tax authorities (Warda, 2006). Yet there are also countries that do not have any of the three types of R&D-specific tax incentive schemes, as was the case in Germany, Poland and Sweden in 2006 (Table 2).4

    Apart from the different statutory corporate tax rates that vary from 12.5% (Ireland) to 35% (Spain) in 2006, Table 2 also delivers an overview of the R&D specific depreciation rules applied in selected OECD countries, when the normal tax life for equipment is assumed to be 10 years. For example, free depreciation (FD) was most widely applied in OECD countries including Canada, France, Ireland, the Netherlands and the UK (see the fourth column of Table 2). The third column of Table 2 suggests that in many countries (e.g. Australia, Belgium, Canada, Denmark, France, Ireland, Japan, Portugal, Sweden, the UK and the US) even a firm’s normal investment activity was stimulated mostly by generous geometric-degressive depreciation (GDD) in the same year. On the basis of such ‘normal’ depreciation rules (in the third column) additional incentive effects of R&D-specific depreciation rules (and also tax allowances and tax credits) can be identified.

    [Table 2.] Tax incentive measures for R&D equipment investment in selected OECD countries when normal tax life = 10 years (2006)

    label

    Tax incentive measures for R&D equipment investment in selected OECD countries when normal tax life = 10 years (2006)

    In 2006, R&D tax allowances were offered in some OECD countries, including Australia, Austria, Belgium, the Czech Republic, Denmark, Hungary and the UK. Most are volume-based, while Australia and Austria allowed a combination of both level-based and incremental allowances (see also Table 2). For a firm’s R&D investment made in collaboration with public research institutions, a special allowance of 400% (of investment spending) was possible in Hungary.

    Several selected OECD countries allowed R&D tax credits in 2006. As also shown in Table 2, a larger share of countries (e.g. Austria, Canada, Japan and the Netherlands) offered this type of tax incentive based on the total volume of the firm’s R&D investment. On the other hand, purely incremental tax credits were popular in Ireland and the United States, of which amounts are determined as a percentage share of a firm’s R&D spending increase over some base period. France, Portugal and Spain had a mixed system of volume-based and incremental tax credits.5 According to Warda (2006), there has been a shift away from incremental towards volume-based tax credits over time. None of the east European OECD members had such an R&D promotion measure.

    4In addition, the Slovak corporate tax system has not recently provided any specific preferential tax-treatment for R&D investment at all (see Mennel, 2007). According to OECD (2007), Sweden and Germany have traditionally been the OECD countries with the highest GDP share of business expenditures in R&D (BERD), while Poland and Slovakia are positioned at the bottom of the ranking in the period 2001–2005.   5South Korea also offers both a volume-based and an incremental tax credit, but these two credits are mutually exclusive, which means that a firm can claim only one of these credits (Warda, 2006).

    3. Net Present Value Model

       3.1 Modigliani?Miller Theorem of Capital Structure Revisited

    According to Modigliani and Miller (1958), the market value of a firm does not depend upon its capital structure, when conditions are satisfied, such as perfect markets (i.e. no taxes or transaction costs); the cash flows that are independent of financial structure; and riskless debt such that firms and individuals can borrow and lend at a risk free interest rate.

    When (i) an investment costing C generates an infinite stream of future gross return; (ii) the return exponentially declines at rate α (0 < α < 1); and (iii) all prices are constant over time, an internal equity-financed investment project is on the margin of acceptance at the year of investment

    image

    if

    image

    where A0 = gross return at year u = 0 (A0 > 0); r = real interest rate (0 < r < 1); and

    image

    = present value of asset at year 0 with equity finance. Under the assumption of perfect competitive market structure mentioned above, only one real interest rate exists in the financial market. Additionally, α is the same as Samuleson’s true economic depreciation rate (Samuelson, 1964; Atkinson & Stiglitz, 1980; Nam & Radulescu, 2007).

    In the case of financing the investment cost C through debt, a firm pays the creditor not only the annual interest of rC for s years but also the entire amount of C to the creditor at the end of this maturity year. Therefore, present value of total cost at year 0

    image

    can be expressed:

    image

    Since the annual interest payment reduces the future gross return for s years, the following steady-state condition applies for the debt-financed investment in the absence of tax,

    image

    where

    image

    = present value of asset at year 0 with debt finance.With debt finance,

    image

    when

    image

    Rearranging equations (2) and (3) leads to

    image

    Hence, the traditional Modigliani-Miller theorem applies (see also Nam & Radulescu, 2005).

       3.2 Effects of Tax Incentives for R&D Investment

    In tax policy practice, various tax depreciation measures are employed that do not ensure true economic depreciation. Moreover, their generosity has been extended to stimulate private investment (Atkinson & Stiglitz, 1980; Sinn, 1987; Nam & Radulescu, 2005). For example, in the case of introducing the corporate tax rate t in combination with straight-line depreciation (SLD) over a tax-life of Γ years, the ‘after-tax’ present value of the asset with equity finance at year 0 is

    image

    The application of SLD generates additional tax savings if

    image

    If the same investment is financed by debt completely, then

    image

    With 0 < r < 1, 0 < t < 1 and s > 0, the term 1 − er(1−t)s is always smaller than 1. Therefore

    image

    Furthermore

    image

    When 0 < r < 1, 0 < t < 1 and s > 0, the conditions 0 < ers < 1 and erts > 1 apply. As a consequence,

    image

    is always larger than

    image

    As shown in Table 1, R&D investment of firms is most commonly promoted in OECD countries by allowing specific tax allowances and tax credits, which are often combined with one of more generous tax depreciation rules (i.e. geometricdegressive and free depreciations) than those applied for ‘normal’ investments. In 2006, for instance, the British R&D-specific tax concession consisted of tax allowance (TA) as a percentage share of current investment volume C combined with free depreciation (FD), while the normal investment was promoted by geometric-degressive depreciation (GDD) in this country.When equity financing of R&D investment, NPV(t) equipped with TA and FD at the year 0 can be expressed as follows

    image

    where β = the rate of TA which can be deducted from the tax base at year 1 (0 < β).6 Moreover, the total investment cost C is fully written off at year 1 since FD is applied.

    Analogous to equation (7), with debt financing

    image

    Hence, the ‘additional’ investment promotion effect of an R&D-specific tax concession over GDD provided for normal investment in the UK is, with internal equity finance

    image

    where δ = the GDD rate (0 < δ < 1) and Ceδu = the net book value of capital good in the period u.7

    On the other hand, with debt finance

    image

    Taking the UK as an example, the comparison of equations (10) and (11) demonstrates that the additional investment promotion effect of generous R&D-specific tax concessions (and their combinations) over that of other standard tax depreciations allowed for normal investment projects remains unchanged, regardless of whether investment cost is covered by internal equity or debt.

    6Analogously, the present value of tax saving that is generated by the deduction of an R&D-specific tax credit (TC) as a percentage share of current investment volume C from the payable tax amount at year 0 can be described as where γ = the rate of TC (0 < γ < 1). Similar to the case with TA, equation (F.1) can also be combined with various tax depreciation rules. For example, with FD (as was the case in Canada, France and the Netherlands in 2006) equation (8) can be modified correspondingly to In the case of adopting incremental TA and/or TC, their amounts are determined as a percentage share of a firm’s R&D spending increase (Y) over some base period, instead of C.   7If δ = α, then When δ < α, the corporate tax system does not provide any incentives at all regardless of the level of tax rate (0 < t < 1) and, therefore, the condition prevails. With δ > α, applies, which, in turn, means that GDD provides incentives in combination with t. In this case a corporate tax rate tmax exists, which maximises (see also Nam & Radulescu, 2005):

    4. Major Results of Model Simulation

    Under the consideration of different financial methods of R&D investments, this empirical section compares the effects of R&D-specific tax incentives on a firm’s after-tax NPV in 19 selected OECD countries for the year 2006. Two types of tax policy measures – statutory corporate tax rates and preferable tax treatment of R&D investment shown in Table 2 – differ from one country to another in the model simulation, whereas other relevant parameters such as real interest rate, economic depreciation, etc are given. Common assumptions made in the simulations are A0 = 100; r = 5%, α = δ = 20%, C = PV0 = 400, Γ = 10 years for R&D equipment,while incremental R&D tax credits and/or allowances are calculated based on Y = 200.

    Basically two different types of calculations on investment promotion effects are carried out in this empirical part: the first after-tax NPV computation for the case when the amount of R&D tax allowance and tax credit is measured on the basis of current investment volume C(=400), and the second when its determination is made based on investment increment Y. Due to such a difference in the calculation basis, a direct comparison of these two cases to each other appears to be less meaningful and, as already mentioned above, the amount of Y is assumed to be 200, far smaller than C. In the countries where generous R&D-specific tax depreciation (like free depreciation) prevails, tax allowance or tax credit is combined with this R&D-specific depreciation rule when calculating the cumulative after-tax NPV. In the absence of such a depreciation rule, the ‘normal’ tax depreciation applies for the same purpose. The after-tax NPV can also be determined solely by tax saving generated from generous R&D-oriented depreciation rules if the investigated countries are not equipped with the matching tax allowance and tax credit system.

    First, taking the British R&D promotion system as an example, Table 3 illustrates the changes of after-tax NPV according to the variation of the corporate tax rate t. Such a numerical analysis is interesting, since equation (F.3) in Footnote 7 suggests, unlike the conventional wisdom, the possibility of existing tmax with which

    image

    reaches maximum.With δ = 25%, column (II) shows that

    image

    is a ∩–shaped function of t and its amount is the highest when t is around 55%. A similar trend can also be observed in column (IV) with

    image

    when free depreciation is introduced as a R&D-specific incentive measure. For a given t, a comparison of difference between columns (III) and (II) on the one hand, and that made between columns (VI) and (VII) on the other, confirm that

    image

    Column (III) additionally highlights that ceteris paribus

    image

    continuously grows with t. This fact, in turn, signals that the investment promotion effect led by debt finance gets more rapidly larger than

    image

    changes, when t increases. A comparable development is also observed for

    image

    as well as

    image

    in columns (V), (VI) and (VII) in the same table, for which the positive effect of 125% R&D-specific tax allowances play a dominant role in particular. These empirical findings have a somewhat adverse tax policy implication, namely that by given depreciation rules or R&D-specific tax incentives, a more intensive promotion of firms’ (R&D-specific) investments can be achieved in combination with a higher t.

    [Table 3.] Effects of tax incentives for R&D investment classified into corporate tax rate

    label

    Effects of tax incentives for R&D investment classified into corporate tax rate

    Among the surveyed OECD countries, Germany, Poland andSweden treated the R&D investment activities of private firms the same as different types of capital formation in 2006. Under the assumption of relevant parameters made above, the German and the Polish corporate tax rules did not provide any incentives at all when the R&D investment is financed by internal equity – a fact that is expressed in terms of negative NPV(t)0 values in column (VII) of Table 4.

    Columns (VIII) and (XI) of Table 4 demonstrate the after-tax NPV of OECD members when the rates of R&D tax incentive measures are calculated on the basis of current investment volume (i.e. C = 400): the former column shows the case with internal equity finance and the latter with debt finance. Although free depreciation applied in countries like France, the UK, and Canada also played a certain role in 2006, R&D-specific TA was the incentive measure that generated the most substantial tax saving (see also column III). In this year, the top after-tax NPV ranking group was led by the Czech Republic and consisted of Belgium, the UK, Denmark, Hungary andAustria aswell asAustralia, in descending order – all these countries had a generous TA scheme. Equipped with TC, Canada, Portugal, Spain and the Netherlands were in the middle ranking group, while Luxembourg with the sole R&D-oriented GDD of 40% was in last position among the 15 OECD countries shown in columns (VIII) and (XI) of Table 4.

    If the rates of tax allowance and tax credit are exclusively imposed on the incremental sum of investment (Y = 200), the country ranking of the after-tax NPV is differently structured. Again, in spite of the absence of an incremental TC and TA system, the lowest ranked countries, such as Hungary, Luxembourg, Belgium, Canada, the Netherlands and the UK, are also illustrated in columns (IV) and (XII) of Table 4, since they had R&D-specific depreciation.Regardless of whether the R&D investment is financed by internal equity or debt, for example, the sole application of the SLD of 20% made Hungary (together with Luxembourg) place at the bottom of country rankings in 2006. Unlike the case with volume-based computation, however, the countries with a generous TC on Y, such as France, Portugal and Spain, ranked at the top, followed by Australia and Austria endowed with the incremental TA.

    [Table 4.] Comparison of effects of tax incentives for R&D investment in OECD countries in 2006

    label

    Comparison of effects of tax incentives for R&D investment in OECD countries in 2006

    5. Conclusion

    This study deals with the preferential tax treatment of R&D investment in selected OECD countries. Many member countries have exceptionally kept and even extended such a tax-base subsidy system as an important technology and innovation policy measure, although they have recently carried out a series of ‘taxrate-cut-cum-base-broadening’ corporate tax reforms. This fact suggests that there has been a sort of tax competition among the OECD countries regarding R&D promotion.

    Clearly differentiating financing methods between internal equity and debt finance, this study computes and compares the after-tax NPV in order to identify the generosity of various types of tax incentives implemented in OECD countries that are aimed at stimulating firms’R&Dinvestments in the context of a corporate tax system. Analogous to many other previous research findings, this study also confirms that the corporate tax system favours debt finance, since by a given tax depreciation scheme the absolute amount of after-tax NPV with debt finance exceeds that with internal equity finance.Yet, the major reasons for the superiority of debt finance encompass more than the conventional deductibility of interest payment from the tax base, which creates extra tax savings. For example, with debt finance, annual gross profits are also reduced by the amount of interest payments, from which the entire corporate tax burden is subtracted to calculate the post-tax profits. Moreover, compared to the investment cost covered by firms’ internal equity, the present value of debt-financed investment cost considered in the calculation of the after-tax NPV is lower, since discounting (with the real interest rate) occurs for the repayment of the entire debt sum at the end of the given maturity years. However, the preponderance of internal equity finance for R&D investment can hardly be explained in relation to the corporate tax incentive system, because the additional promotion effects (also expressed in terms of the post-tax NPV) of generous R&D-specific tax incentives over the standard depreciation rules (allowed for usual fixed capital investments) in the individual OECD countries, remain unchanged regardless of the financing method.

    The OECD comparison demonstrates that R&Dtax allowanceswere the incentive measure that generated the most substantial tax savings in 2006. In this year the top after-tax NPV ranking group was led by the Czech Republic, followed by Belgium, the UK, Denmark, Hungary and Austria as well as Australia – all these countries had a R&D allowance scheme. Endowed with R&D tax credit, Canada, Portugal, Spain and the Netherlands belong to the middle ranking group. Notably, with such tax allowances and tax credits, the after-tax NPV ceteris paribus increases with the corporate tax rate. This positive correlation, in turn, suggests the possibility of achieving a stronger R&D investment promotion by adopting a ‘tax-rate-increase-cum-base-broadening’ policy, instead of the tax-rate-cut-cum-base-broadening type that is dominant in OECD countries.

참고문헌
  • 1. Atkinson A.B., Stiglitz J.E. (1980) Lectures on Public Economics google
  • 2. Bagella M., Becchetti L., Caggese A. (2001) Financial constraints on investment: a three pillar approach [Research in Economics] Vol.55 P.219-254 google cross ref
  • 3. Berger P.G. (1993) Explicit and implicit tax effects of the R&D tax credit [Journal of Accounting Research] Vol.31 P.131-172 google cross ref
  • 4. Bernstein J.I. (1986) The effect of direct and indirect tax incentives on Canadian industrial R&D expenditures [Canadian Public Policy] Vol.12 P.438-448 google cross ref
  • 5. Bloom N., Griffith R., van Reenen J. (2002) Do R&D tax credits work?: evidence from an international panel of countries 1979-97 [Journal of Public Economics] Vol.85 P.1-31 google cross ref
  • 6. Brown J.R., Fazzari S.M., Petersen B.C. (2007) Financing innovation and growth: cash flow, external equity and the 1990s R&D boom. google
  • 7. Carpenter R., Petersen B. (2002) Capital market imperfections, high-tech investment and new equity financing [Economic Journal] Vol.112 P.54-72 google cross ref
  • 8. Cordes J.J. (1989) Tax incentives and R&D spending: a reviewof the evidence [Research Policy] Vol.18 P.119-133 google cross ref
  • 9. Devereux P.M. (2004) Measuring taxes on income from capital, in: P.B. Sørensen (Ed.) Measuring the Tax Burden on Capital and Labor P.35-71 google
  • 10. Devereux P.M., Griffith R. (2003) Evaluating tax policy for location decisions [International Tax and Public Finance] Vol.10 P.107-126 google cross ref
  • 11. Devereux P.M., Griffith R., Klemm A. (2002) Corporate income tax reforms and international tax competition [Economic Policy] Vol.35 P.451-495 google
  • 12. Griffith R. (2000) How Important Is Business R&D for Economic Growth and Should the Government Subsidise It? IFS Briefing Notes 12 google
  • 13. Grossman G.M., Helpman E. (1991) Innovation and Growth in the Global Economy google
  • 14. Guellec D., van Pottelsberghe B. (2003) The impact of public R&D expenditure on business R&D [Economics of Innovation and New Technology] Vol.12 P.225-243 google cross ref
  • 15. Hall B., van Reenen J. (2000) How effective are fiscal incentives for R&D? A review of the evidence [Research Policy] Vol.29 P.449-469 google cross ref
  • 16. Hubbard G. (1998) Capital market imperfections and investment [Journal of Economic Literature] Vol.35 P.193-225 google
  • 17. King M.A., Fullerton D. (1984) The Taxation of Income from Capital: A Comparative Study of the United States, the United Kingdom, Sweden, and West Germany google
  • 18. McCutchen W.W. (1993) Estimating the impact of theR&Dtax credit on strategic groups in the pharmaceutical industry [Research Policy] Vol.22 P.337-351 google cross ref
  • 19. Mennel A. (2007) Steuern in Europa, USA, Kanada und Japan google
  • 20. Messere K., de Kam F., Heady C. (2003) Tax Policy: Theory and Practice in OECD Countries google
  • 21. Modigliani F., Miller M.H. (1958) The cost of capital, corporation finance and the theory of investment [American Economic Review] Vol.48 P.261-297 google
  • 22. Mulkay B., Mairesse J. (2004) The effect of the R&D tax credit in France (1980-1997) [Revue d’Economie Politique] Vol.114 P.747-778 google
  • 23. Nam C.W., Radulescu D.M. (2005) The role of tax depreciation for investment decisions ? a comparison of European transition countries [Eastern European Economies] Vol.43 P.5-24 google
  • 24. Nam C.W., Radulescu D.M. (2007) Effects of corporate tax reforms on SMEs’ investment decisions under the particular consideration of inflation [Small Business Economics] Vol.29 P.101-118 google cross ref
  • 25. (2007) Main Science and Technology Indicators google
  • 26. Romer P.M. (1994) The origin of endogenous growth [Journal of Economic Perspectives] Vol.8 P.55-77 google
  • 27. Samuelson P.A. (1964) Tax deductibility of economic depreciation to ensure invariant valuation [Journal of Political Economy] Vol.72 P.604-606 google cross ref
  • 28. Sawyer A. (2005) Reflections on providing tax incentives for research and development: New Zealand at the cross road [Journal of Australian Taxation] Vol.8 P.3 google
  • 29. Sinn H.W. (1987) Capital Income Taxation and Resource Allocation google
  • 30. Sørensen P.B. (2004) Measuring taxes on capital and labor: an overview of methods and issues, in: P.B. Sørensen (Ed.) Measuring the Tax Burden on Capital and Labor P.1-33 google
  • 31. Ughetto E. (2008) Does internal finance matter for R&D? Newevidence froma panel of Italian firms [Cambridge Journal of Economics] Vol.32 P.907-925 google cross ref
  • 32. Warda J. (2006) Tax Treatment of Business Investments in Intellectual Assets: An International Comparison. google
OAK XML 통계
이미지 / 테이블
  • [ Table 1. ]  Positive effects of R&D-specific tax incentives revealed by selected empirical investigations
    Positive effects of R&D-specific tax incentives revealed by selected empirical investigations
  • [ Table 2. ]  Tax incentive measures for R&D equipment investment in selected OECD countries when normal tax life = 10 years (2006)
    Tax incentive measures for R&D equipment investment in selected OECD countries when normal tax life = 10 years (2006)
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ ] 
  • [ Table 3. ]  Effects of tax incentives for R&D investment classified into corporate tax rate
    Effects of tax incentives for R&D investment classified into corporate tax rate
  • [ Table 4. ]  Comparison of effects of tax incentives for R&D investment in OECD countries in 2006
    Comparison of effects of tax incentives for R&D investment in OECD countries in 2006
(우)06579 서울시 서초구 반포대로 201(반포동)
Tel. 02-537-6389 | Fax. 02-590-0571 | 문의 : oak2014@korea.kr
Copyright(c) National Library of Korea. All rights reserved.