검색 전체 메뉴
PDF
맨 위로
OA 학술지
Trust, Capability, and Management Control in International Joint Ventures in Korea: A Dynamic Perspective
  • 비영리 CC BY-NC
ABSTRACT
Trust, Capability, and Management Control in International Joint Ventures in Korea: A Dynamic Perspective
KEYWORD
International Joint Venture , Trust , Capability , Management Control , Bargaining Power
  • Ⅰ. Introduction

    One of the richest streams of research in joint venture (JV) studies has centered on parent control exercised over joint ventures (JVs). Recent work on how parent firms choose from among various control mechanisms (Kumar and Seth 1998; Barden et al. 2005), how parent firms partition control over the JV’s management between JV partners (Yan and Gary 1994: Child et al. 1997; Mjoen and Tallman 1997; Brouthers and Bamossy 1997; Cardinal et al. 2004; Kamminga et al. 2007; Chen et al. 2009), and how parent firms’ partitions of management control is correlated with their satisfaction with JV performance (Yan and Gray 1994; Mjoen and Tallman 1997; Luo et al., 2001; Luo 2003; Choi and Beamish 2004) all focus on the issue of parent control in JVs.

    However, what is missing from these studies is an examination of the dynamic aspects of parent control in joint ventures. Chen et al. (2009) point out that it is a long-standing omission in JV theory. The research question of the paper is what causes the change in the existing division of management control between the partners. It is important to understand the major cause of control change. Given the evidence of a control-performance relationship (Choi and Beamish, 2004), achieving desired performance is associated with parent firms building and modifying their amount of control accordingly. To keep securing appropriate amounts of control, parent firms require knowledge regarding the antecedent of control change.

    Parent control is defined as influence exercised by the parents over the JV’s management (Luo et al., 2001; Choi and Beamish 2004; Chen et al. 2009). The control partitioned between the partners, thus, represents the relative influence of both partners on the JV's management. Drawing on the bargaining power theory (Thibaut and Kelley 1959; Michael 2000), the change in the existing division of management control is theorized as a result of a shift in the existing bargaining power balance between partners. To capture the change in the amount of a joint venture partner's bargaining power, we measure the joint venture partner's capability change. Trust is also examined as an antecedent of a joint venture partners' capability change. So the link "trust -> capability change -> change in the amount of control exercised by the JV partners is examined in the context of international joint ventures in Korea. Data were collected through interviews with 51 international joint ventures in Korea.

    Following the introduction, the bargaining power argument about the initial division of management control between the partners is reviewed. In the Hypothesis Development section, hypotheses associated with trust, capability change, and control change are developed. The research methodology is then discussed. The discussion of the results is presented in the final section of the paper.

    Ⅱ. Literature Review

    According to the bargaining power argument, the MNE (multinational enterprise)’ s control over its foreign subsidiary is thought to be determined by the interaction between the MNE and its local counterpart. This argument was first applied to the bargaining situation between the MNE and the host government, primarily from less developed countries (LDCs) where the host governments were key stakeholders in foreign direct investment (FDI) negotiations (Gomes-Casseres 1989; Blodgett 1991; Yan and Gray 1994; Pan 1996; Brouthers and Bamossy 1997).

    In such bargaining situations, the MNE usually possesses the capital, technology, management, and marketing skills needed to launch an FDI project successfully, while the host government has control over the access to its domestic market, natural resources, and other conditions for the successful operation of the MNE in its own country. To maintain economic independence from the MNE’s control over its domestic economy, the host government struggles with the MNE over the division of the JV's management control and the distribution of the payoffs from the joint venture. What determines the outcome of that struggle is thought to be the MNE's or the host government's bargaining power stemming from the asymmetric dependent relationship between the MNE and the host government. Therefore, the MNE’s achieved management control over its foreign subsidiary is hypothesized to be a reflection of the relative bargaining power between the MNE and the host government. It has been found that the most important source of the MNE’s bargaining power is technology, followed by financial resources and management expertise (Blodgett 1991; Pan 1996; Brouthers and Bamossy 1997).

    The bargaining power argument has been further extended to the bargaining situation between an MNE and a local firm, excluding a host government from the negotiation over JV control (Yan and Gray 1996; Child et al. 1997;Mjoen and Tallman 1997). The source of bargaining power is thought to be based on the critical resources the MNE and the local firm contribute to the joint venture. Recognizing a firm’s resources as a source of the rent (Wernerfelt 1985; Barney 1986, 1991; Dierickx and Cool, 1989), scholars in this research stream conceived the parent firms' initial resource commitments to the venture as forming their bargaining power base. In other words, the importance of a JV partner's initial resource contribution relative to its partner’s inputs to the venture determines the level of its bargaining power and the resulting extent of management control. The rationale is that a partner who contributes less will eventually depend more on the other partner for the operation of the venture. The asymmetric dependence, in turn, sets the tone for the bargaining process between the partners. This argument received strong support in the empirical studies that captured the positive relationship between the parent firms' control and initial resource commitments (Yan and Gray 1996; Child et al. 1997; Mjoen and Tallman 1997).

    Using the initial resource contribution as a measure of the parent firms' bargaining power, previous studies succeeded in predicting the initial division of management control between the partners (Yan and Gray 1996; Child et al. 1997; Mjoen and Tallman 1997). Indeed, the resources contributed at the founding of the JV can have a lasting effect on the evolution of the joint venture. In their case study of four joint ventures between US and Chinese firms, Yan (1998) documents how well the initial balance of bargaining power is retained over time through continuous adjustment actions by both partners. Such adjustment actions occurred whenever the parent firms' relative bargaining power significantly shifted from its original state.

    What the literature reviewed so far has in common is that they all limited their attention to the initial state of the bargaining power balance and the resulting division of management control between partners. However, as indicated by recent researchers (Inkpen and Beamish 1997; Cardinal et al. 2004; Kamminga et al. 2007; Chen et al. 2009), the bargaining power of the JV partners is not static but dynamic over the course of the JV’s lifetime. In the following section of the paper, it is argued that the change in the bargaining power is caused by the change in the JV partners' capabilities because the relative bargaining power between partners is a reflection of their underlying resource or capability dependence. By resource or capability dependence we mean the partners’ interdependent or complementary relationship in terms of their resources or capabilities. In short, the relative bargaining power of partners can be considered a representation of their relative capabilities. Then, the bargaining power and the resulting extent of the management control of the partners is likely to last as long as the relative capabilities of partners remain unchanged.

    To completely examine the capability change-control change relationship, we incorporate "trust" into our research model. Trust is hypothesized as an antecedent of capability change. So the link "trust-> capability change-> control change" is examined as the complete research model of our paper.

    Ⅲ. Hypothesis Development

    Figure 1 depicts this study's research model. The change in the existing division of management control is theorized as the result of a shift in the existing bargaining power balance between the joint venture partners. To capture the change in the amount of the joint venture partners' bargaining power, we measure the joint venture partners’ capability change. Trust is also examined as an antecedent of the joint venture partners' capability change. So the link "trust -> capability change -> control change" is examined in this paper.

       1. Setting of the Study

    Korea is a research setting where developed market partners and local Korean partners join forces to form JVs. Developed market partners typically contribute technology-related resources to the venture while local Korean partners contribute local knowledge-related resources. Technology-related resources that developed market partners contribute to the venture are defined as the ones employed to develop the JV's products and production processes. Such resources have been found to be those that local emerging market firms seek most when selecting developed country partners (Hitt et al. 2000, 2004; Lyles & Salk 2007). Local firms' needs for technology-related resources originate from a technology gap existing between developed and emerging market countries. Blodgett (1991) found that technology provides the most powerful leverage for developed market firms when they negotiate with local emerging market firms for the division of JV equity ownership. In contrast, developed market partners' major criterion for selecting local partners is whether local firms possess local knowledge-related resources that the developed-market firms lack (Hitt et al. 2000, 2004; Fang & Zou 2009). Developed market partners' needs for local resources is attributed to the context difference between developed and emerging markets, as advanced by resource-based theorists emphasizing the context-specific nature of rent-earning resources (Madhok 1996, 1997). The greater the difference that exists between the developed and emerging market context, the stronger will be the developed market firms' needs for local knowledge-related resources. In these cases, a local partner's firm-specific advantages are derived mostly from the local partner's knowledge of the local culture, customs, and market characteristics, from simply being an indigenous firm that enjoys preferential treatment by the local government or from its position in the local network of organizational relationships important to the successful operation of a business. Local knowledge-related resources are specifically defined as the resources that consist of local marketing skills, local personnel management skills, and local distribution channel management skills.

       2. Trust and Capability Change

    Trust between the JV partners is important in creating a foundation for learning. Without trust during the collaborative process, information exchanged between the partners may be low in accuracy (Currall and Judge 1995). Conversely, an atmosphere of trust should contribute to the free exchange of information between committed exchanged partners, because decision makers do not feel that they have to protect themselves from the others' opportunistic behavior (Blau 1964). This suggests that inter-firm trust is a key variable that determines knowledge accessibility. As trust develops over time, learning opportunities will increase and each partner will decrease their efforts to protect their knowledge and skills.

    In fact, for the JV partner whose knowledge is being acquired, the risk of knowledge spillover exists. Knowledge spillover occurs when valuable firm knowledge spills out to competitors, who can then use the knowledge to gain a competitive advantage (Cohen and Levinthal 1990). When there is high inter-partner trust, knowledge spillovers are acknowledged to be an inevitable result of joint venture involvement (Inkpen and Currall 2004). Although a JV partner risks knowledge spillover, there is also the opportunity to capitalize on spillovers of the other partner's knowledge. Thus, firms may be able to learn more than they lose and build valuable learning ability in the process. In short, as inter-partner trust increases, partner willingness to provide access to information is likely to increase, thus providing the foundation for partner learning. For the local Korean partner who depends on the foreign partner for the JV's technology, the increase in a degree of trust between partners will increase the learning opportunities, thus leading to the increase in the Korean partner's technology-related capability. On the other hand, for the foreign partner who depends on the Korean partner for the JV's local knowledge, the increase in the degree of trust between partners will increase the learning opportunities, thus leading to the increase in the foreign partner's local knowledge-related capability. The reasoning so far leads to the following hypotheses.

       3. Capability Change and Control Change

    Learning that involves the acquisition of partner knowledge can be a powerful basis for bargaining and JV control. Hamel (1991) argued that the bargaining power vested in a particular firm will almost certainly erode if its partner is more adept at learning the other’s skills or quicker to build valuable new competencies. According to the bargaining power theory that sees power as central to the relationship between the parties concerned (Thibaut and Kelley 1959; Michael 2000), the inter-partner capability transfer through learning triggers the change in the bargaining power balance between partners. In other words, the outcome of learning is the reduction of the dependence of one partner on the other for the operation of the JV. The reduced dependence, in turn, upsets the existing asymmetric dependence that shaped the original bargaining power balance. This newly shaped dependent relationship between partners increases or decreases the one or the other partner's bargaining power, which is eventually used to increase or decrease the control exercised over the JV's management. According to Hamel (1991), JV partners’ intents to exploit the increased bargaining power is important in leading to the increased control over the JV. For the hypothesis development, it is assumed that JV partners have the intention to exploit the increased bargaining power for the acquisition of control in the JV.

    What if one partner refuses to accept the reality that the existing bargaining power balance between them has changed? In that case, trust between partners is likely to be damaged, thus leading to JV instability. Yan (1998) reports about a joint venture case in which the U.S. partner keeps proposing to add one more U.S. member to the venture’s board of directors to justify the U.S. firm’s increased bargaining power. The Chinese local partner’s refusal of the repeated proposal made the U.S. partner unhappy and eventually damaged the relationship between the partners. He further reports that “the unhappy U.S. partner eventually threatened not to renew its technology transfer agreement with the venture, and started creating a new venture with a different local firm.” Yan’s observation suggests that partners experiencing reduced bargaining power are forced to match the newly shaped bargaining power balance by giving up of some management control over the JV. The match thus achieved will, in turn, create a sense of equity and fairness that enhances trust between partners (Johnson et al. 2002).

    Based on the reasoning so far, we can expect that an increase in the parent firm's capability will lead to an increase in the parent firm's bargaining power, and then eventually an increase in the management control exercised over the JV. For the local Korean partner who depends on the foreign partner for the JV's technology, the increase in the local Korean partner's technology-related capability will increase the Korean partner's bargaining power in the area of technology, thus leading to the increase in the technology-related control exercised by the Korean partner over the JV. On the other hand, for the foreign partner who depends on the Korean partner for the JV's local knowledge, the increase in the foreign partner's local knowledge-related capability will increase the foreign partner's bargaining power in the area of local knowledge, thus leading to the increase in the local knowledge-related control exercised by the foreign partner over the JV. The reasoning so far leads to the following hypotheses.

    Ⅳ. Methodology

       1. Sample and data collection

    The data for this study were collected in 2010 through in-person, semistructured interviews with Korean general or deputy general managers of Korean-U.S., Korean-Japanese, or Korean-European manufacturing JVs. The 2010 edition of Foreign Direct Investment in Korea, published by the Ministry of Knowledge and Economy of the Korean government, served as a sampling frame in which a total of 200 qualifying Korean-U.S., Korean- Japanese, and Korean-European manufacturing JVs were drawn. The 2010 edition of the directory included listings of all international JVs that had been formed in Korea since 1980. The sampling criteria for selecting 200 JVs were: (1) JVs whose foreign partners contributed most of the technology at the formation of the JV while the local Korean partners contributed most of the local knowledge-related skills; (2) JVs involving only two JV partners; (3) JVs in which neither partner held more than 70 percent of the venture’s equity; (4) JVs that derived at least 40% of total sales from the local Korean market; and (5) JVs formed between 1996 and 2006.

    As Foreign Direct Investment in Korea (Ministry of Knowledge and Economy, 2010) did not contain information about the JV's local sales and JV partners' resource contributions, we contacted each firm by telephone to make sure that the JVs randomly sampled from the directory met the selection criteria. Initial contact with the 200 sample JVs was made with cover letters provided by the author. A week later, each of the JV’s general managers was contacted by telephone to secure his or her cooperation. Following their agreement to participate in the study, a site visit was made for the interview. Of the 200 JVs, 51 firms finally agreed to participate in the study, giving a participation rate of 25.5%. In-person interviews were conducted for three months with the help of two other professors in the area of international business. When the JV’s general manager had not been involved in the JV’s management long enough to be familiar with the JV's recent history, he was asked for a more suitable individual for a further interview.

    To check the non-response bias, we compared the 51 responding firms with the 149 non-responding firms for the following three characteristics: foreign ownership (percentage), JV size (total capital investment), and JV age (number of years since foundation). The t-test results were all insignificant, indicating that there was no important non-response bias in our sample.

    The sample distribution of the foreign parents’ nationalities closely follows the study population’s distribution. Parent firms from Japan made up 57.7 percent of the sample. The remaining sample was made up of parent firms from the EU (19.7 percent) and the U.S. and Canada (22.5 percent). JVs that were involved in the electric and electronic sector comprised 25 percent of the sample. The next most common sectors were machinery (21 percent) and chemicals (19 percent). This industry distribution also closely mirrors the study population’s distribution. Both industry and foreign parents’ nationality were controlled for in subsequent analyses.

       2. Variables and Measures

       1) Management control variables

    The local Korean partner's technology-related control in the JV was measured along the following three managerial activities: (1) the control of product technology, (2) the control of process technology, (3) the control of choice of key technology. The foreign partner's local knowledge-related control in the JV was measured along the following three managerial activities: (1) the control of local marketing, (2) the control of local personnel management, and (3) the control of the management of the local distribution channel.

    For these measures, general managers were asked to evaluate the extent to which the Korean (foreign) partner has increased control (or influence) over each of the managerial activities over the last 5-10 years (1=no increase, 2=slightly increase, 3=medium increase, 4=significantly increase, 5=very highly increase). This five-point Likert-type scale represents the increase in the amount of control exercised by each partner over the JV’s management during the last 5-10 years.

    2) Capability variables

    The Korean partner's technology-related capability was measured along the two dimensions of (1) product technology and (2) process technology. The foreign partner's local knowledge-related capability was measured along the three dimensions of (1) local marketing, (2) local personnel management, and (3) the management of the local distribution channel. For these measures, general managers were asked to assess the extent to which the Korean (foreign) partner has enhanced capability for each of the managerial activities over the last 5-10 years(1=no increase, 2=slightly increase, 3=medium increase, 4=significantly increase, 5=very highly increase). This five-point Likert-type scale represents the increase in the amount of capabilities during the last 5-10 years.

    3) Trust variables

    Trust was measured with a five-point Likert-type scale adapted from Currall and Inkpen (2002). General managers were asked to indicate their agreement or disagreement (1=Strongly disagree, 3=Neither disagree nor agree, 5=Strongly agree) with the following statements, given the partner-relationship that has been formed during the last 5-10 years:

    The first of three items was a reverse statement which was reverse-coded so that higher scores represent higher levels of trust.

       3. Analysis and Results

    The partial least squares (PLS) technique was selected for the analysis of the causal modeling. PLS is an appropriate technique when sample sizes are small, when data normality and interval-scaled data cannot be assumed, and when the goal is the prediction of the dependent variables.

    1) Measurement model: validity and reliability

    In assessing the measurement model, the principal concern was with the internal consistency and the reliability of the items in the multiple-item constructs. The reliability of individual items was determined by the inspection of item loadings on the respective constructs. In all cases, all individual items had a high degree of reliability as each loading exceeded 0.7 (Table 1). Convergent validity was assessed using internal consistency, a measure similar to Cronbach's alpha (Table 2). As reported in Table 1, all constructs had internal consistencies greater than 0.90, demonstrating strong convergent validity. Discriminant validity was gauged by comparing the correlation matrix constructs (Table 3). For each construct in Table 3, the diagonal elements (average variance extracted) were greater than the numbers in the associated row or column, suggesting a good discriminant validity. In other words, the correlations between constructs off the diagonal were smaller than the square root of the AVE (average variance extracted) on the diagonal.

    [Table 1] Maximum Likelihood Factor Analysis: Varimax Rotation

    label

    Maximum Likelihood Factor Analysis: Varimax Rotation

    [Table 2] Measurement Model

    label

    Measurement Model

    [Table 3] Discriminant Validity

    label

    Discriminant Validity

    2) Structural model

    Given the adequacy of the measurement model, it is appropriate to proceed with interpretation of the structural model. Table 4 reports the outcomes of the hypothesis testing and the explained variance in the model's endogenous constructs. All of the study's four hypotheses were supported, and the model explained 43.7% of the variance in the control change of the joint ventures.

    Hypothesis 1a predicted that trust between the partners is positively related to the Korean partner's technology-related capability. Consistent with the prediction of Hypothesis 1a, the positive significant path coefficient on Trust in Model 1 indicates that an increase in the degree of trust between the partners will lead to the increase in the Korean partner's technology-related capability. Hypothesis 1b predicted that trust between the partners is positively related to the foreign partner's local knowledge-related capability. Consistent with the prediction of Hypothesis 1b, the positive significant path coefficient on Trust in Model 2 indicates that an increase in the degree of trust between the partners will also lead to the increase in the foreign partner's local knowledge-related capability.

    [Table 4] Summary of the Path Estimates (N=51)

    label

    Summary of the Path Estimates (N=51)

    Path coefficient testing Hypothesis 2a, showing that the local Korean partner's technology-related capability is positively related to the local Korean partner's technology-related control, was found to be significant. This suggests that an increase in the local Korean partner's technology-related capability will eventually lead to the increase in the local Korean partner's technology-related control exercised over the JV. Path coefficient testing Hypothesis 2b, showing that the foreign partner's local knowledge-related capability is positively related to the foreign partner's local knowledge-related control, was also found to be significant. This suggests that an increase in the foreign partner's local knowledge-related capability will eventually lead to the increase in the foreign partner's local knowledge-related control exercised over the JV.

    As for the control variables, JV age was positively related to the Korean partner's technology-related control and foreign partner's local knowledge-related control, while JV size was not related. The significance of JV age suggests that the older JVs become, the more change in control happens between the partners.

    Ⅴ. Discussion

    This paper extends the study of parent control exercised over a JV’s management by examining what causes the existing division of management control between partners. The change in the existing division of management control was theorized as a result of a shift in the existing bargaining power balance between partners. To capture the change in the amount of the joint venture partner's bargaining power, we measured the joint venture partner's capability change. To completely examine the capability change-control change relationship, we incorporate "trust" into our research model. Trust was hypothesized as an antecedent of capability change. So the link "trust-> capability change-> control change" was examined as a complete research model of our paper in the context of international joint ventures in Korea.

    Trust between partners was found to be positively related to both the Korean partner's technology-related capability and the foreign partner's local knowledge-related capability. In other words, it was found that the increase in the degree of trust leads to the increase in both the Korean partner's technology-related capability and the foreign partner's local knowledge-related capability. This finding suggests that trust is the foundation for learning from the partner. When trust is low, learning cannot happen properly in the joint venture. Low degrees of trust lead to the fear of opportunism, thus increasing the perceived need for protection against the other partner's opportunistic behavior. In such a situation, the free exchange of information or knowledge between partners is severly limited, thus leading to a low level of learning as well as joint venture instability. Low levels of learning cannot create both partners' capability change.

    Technology-related and local knowledge-related capabilities were found to be positively related to technology-related and local knowledge-related control. In other words, it was found that the increase in the technology-related and local knowledge-related capabilities led to the increase in the technology-related and local knowledge-related control, respectively. The finding suggests that, in the case of joint ventures between developed market firms and local  Korean firms, the foreign partners contributing technology to the venture are likely to lose their power and the resulting management control over the JV's technology to the local Korean partner. Likewise, the local Korean partners contributing local knowledge-related capabilities to the venture are also likely to lose their power and the resulting management control over the JV's local knowledge to the foreign partners.

    This study has some limitations that future research needs to address. The first concerns the small sample size of the study. Because this study adopted in-person interviews as the research method, we could not collect a large size of sample. So, in order to further validate this study's findings, future research needs to conduct a study using a larger size sample.

    A second limitation is the generalizability of the findings. This study examined international joint ventures(IJV) in Korea. Based on this, the interpretation of the findings should be limited to the IJVs in Korea only. This study should be replicated in other countries to generalize the findings.

    Ⅵ. Conclusion

    This study has added to our understanding of the dynamics of parent control. As expected, the local Korean partner's technology-related capability is linked to the local Korean partner's technology-related control, and the foreign partner's local knowledge-related capability is related to the foreign partner's local knowledge-related control. The more the local Korean partner's technology- related capability increases, the more likely that the local Korean partner's technology- related control increases. Likewise, the more the foreign partner's local knowledge-related capability increases, the more likely that the foreign partner's local knowledge-related control increases. Trust was also found to facilitate an increase in both partners' capabilities through learning.

참고문헌
  • 1. Barden J. Q., Steensma H. K., Lyles M. A. (2005) “The Influence of Parent Control Structure on Parent Conflict in Vietnamese International Joint Ventures: An Organizational Justice-based Contingency Approach” [Journal of International Business Studies] Vol.36 P.156-174 google
  • 2. Barney¸ J. B. (1986) “Strategic Factor Markets: Expectations, Luck and Business Strategy” [Management Science] Vol.42 P.1231-1241 google cross ref
  • 3. Barney¸ J. B. (1991) “Firm Resources and Sustained Competitive Advantage” [Journal of Management] Vol.17 P.99-120 google cross ref
  • 4. Blau P. M. (1964) Exchange and Power in Social Life google
  • 5. Blodgett L. L. (1991) “Partner Contributions as Predictors of Equity Share in International Joint Venture” [Journal of International Business Studies] Vol.21 P.63-78 google cross ref
  • 6. Brouthers K. D., Bamossy G. J. (1997) “The Role of Key Stakeholders in International Joint Venture Negotiations: Case Studies from Eastern Europe” [Journal of International Business Studies] Vol.28 P.285-308 google cross ref
  • 7. Cardinal L, Sitkin S. B, Long C. P. (2004) “Balancing and Rebalancing in the Creation and Evolution of Organizational Control” [Organizational Science] Vol.15 P.411-431 google cross ref
  • 8. Chen D., Park S. H., Newburry W. (2009) “Parent Contribution and Organizational Control in International Joint Ventures” [Strategic Management Journal] Vol.30 P.1133-1156 google cross ref
  • 9. Child J., Yan Y., Lu Y. (1997) “Ownership and Control in Sino-Foreign Joint Ventures,” In Paul W. Beamish and J. Peter Killing (Eds.), Cooperative Strategies-Asian Pacific Perspectives google
  • 10. Choi C-B, Beamish P. W. (2004) “Split Management Control and International Joint Venture Performance” [Journal of International Business Studies] Vol.35 P.285-308 google cross ref
  • 11. Cohen W. M., Levinthal D. A. (1990) “Absorptive Capacity: A New Perspective on Learning and Innovation” [Administrative Science Quartly] Vol.35 P.128-152 google cross ref
  • 12. Currall S. C, Inkp A. C. (2002) “A Multilevel Approach to Trust in Joint Ventures” [Journal of International Business Studies] Vol.33 P.479-495 google cross ref
  • 13. Currall S. C., Judge T. A. (1995) “Measuring trust between organizational boundary role persons” [Organization Behavior Human Decision Processes] Vol.64 P.151-170 google cross ref
  • 14. Dierickx I., Cool K. (1989) “Asset Stock Accumulation and Sustainability of Competitive Advantage” [Management Science] Vol.35 P.504-1511 google
  • 15. Gomes-Casseres B. (1989) “Ownership Structures of Foreign Subsidiaries: Theory and Evidence” [Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization] Vol.11 P.1-25 google
  • 16. Fang E, Zou S. (2009) “Antecedents and Consequences of Marketing Dynamic Capabilities in International Joint Ventures” [Journal of International Business Studies] Vol.40 P.742-761 google cross ref
  • 17. Hamel G. (1991) “Competition for Competence and Inter-Partner Learning within International Strategic Alliances” [Strategic Management Journal] Vol.12 P.83-103 google cross ref
  • 18. Hitt M. A., Ahlstrom D., Dacin M. T., Levitas E., Svobodina L. (2004) The “Institutional Effects on Strategic Alliance Partner Selection in Transition Economies: China vs. Russia” [Organization Science] Vol.15 P.173-185 google cross ref
  • 19. Hitt M. A., Dacin M. T., Levitas E., Arregle J. L., Borza A. (2000) “Partner Selection in Emerging and Developed Market Context: Resource-based and Organizational Learning Perspectives” [Academy of Management Journal] Vol.43 P.449-467 google cross ref
  • 20. Inkpen A. C., Beamish W. P. (1997) “Knowledge, Bargaining Power, and the Instability of International Joint Ventures” [Academy of Management Journal] Vol.22 P.177-202 google
  • 21. Inkpen A. C., Currall S. C. (2004) “The Coevolution of Trust Control, and Learning in Joint Ventures” [Organization Science] Vol.15 P.586-599 google cross ref
  • 22. Johnson J. P., Korsgaard M. A., Sapienza H. J. (2002) “Perceived Fairness, Decision Control, and Commitment in International Joint Venture Management Teams” [Strategic Management Journal] Vol.23 P.1141-1160 google cross ref
  • 23. Kamminga P. E., Van der Meer-Kooistra J. (2007) “Management Control Patterns in Joint Venture Relationships: A Model and an Exploratory Study” [Accounting, Organizations and Society] Vol.32 P.131-154 google cross ref
  • 24. Kumar S., Seth A. (1998) “The Design of Coordination and Control Mechanisms for Managing Joint Venture-Parent Relationships” [Strategic Management Journal] Vol.19 P.579-599 google cross ref
  • 25. Lane P. J., Salk J. E, Lyles M. A. (2001) “Absorptive Capacity, Learning, and Performance in International Joint Ventures” [Strategic Management Journal] Vol.22 P.1139-1161 google cross ref
  • 26. Luo Y. (2003) “Market-Seeking MNEs in an Emerging Market: How Parent-Subsidiary Links Shape Overseas Success” [Journal of International Business Studies] Vol.34 P.290-309 google cross ref
  • 27. Luo Y., Shenkar O., Nyaw M-K. (2001) “A Dual Parent Perspective on Control and Performance in International Joint Ventures: Lessons from a Developing Economy” [Journal of International Business Studies] Vol.32 P.41-58 google cross ref
  • 28. Lyles M. A., Salk J. E. (2007) “Knowledge Acquisition from Foreign Partners in International Joint Ventures: An Empirical Examination in the Hungarian Context” [Journal of International Business Studies] Vol.38 P.3-18 google cross ref
  • 29. Madhok A. (1996) “The Organization of Economic Activity: Transaction Costs, Firm Capabilities, and the Nature of Governance” [Organization Science] Vol.7 P.577-590 google cross ref
  • 30. Madhok A. (1997) “Cost, Value, and Foreign Market Entry Mode: The Transaction and the Firm” [Strategic Management Journal] Vol.18 P.39-61 google cross ref
  • 31. Michael S. C. (2000) “Investments to Create Bargaining Power: The Case of Franchising” [Strategic Management Journal] Vol.21 P.497-514 google cross ref
  • 32. (2010) Foreign Direct Investment in Korea google
  • 33. Makhija Mona V., Ganesh Usha (1997) “The Relationship Between Control and Partner Learning in Learning-related Joint Ventures” [Organization Science] Vol.8 P.508-527 google cross ref
  • 34. Mjoen H., Tallman S. (1997) “Control and Performance in International Joint Ventures” [Organizational Science] Vol.8 P.257-274 google cross ref
  • 35. Pan Y. (1996) “Influences on Foreign Equity Ownership Level in Joint Ventures in China” [Journal of International Business Studies] Vol.27 P.1-26 google cross ref
  • 36. Thibaut J. W., Kelley H. (1959) The Social Psychology of Groups google
  • 37. Tsang E. W. K. (2002) “Acquiring Knowledge by Foreign Partners from International Joint Ventures in a Transition Economy: Learning-by-Doing and Learning Myopia,” [Strategic Management Journal] Vol.23 P.835-854 google cross ref
  • 38. Yan Aimin, Gray Barbara (1994) “Bargaining Power, Management Control, and Performance in United States-China Joint Ventures: A Comparative Case Study” [Academy of Management Journal] Vol.37 P.1478-1517 google cross ref
  • 39. Yan A., Gray B. (1996) “Linking Management Control and Interpartner Relationships with Performance in United States-Chinese Joint Ventures. In J. Child and Y. Lu, editors” Management Issues in China: International Enterprises google
  • 40. Yan A. (1998) “Structural Stability and Reconfiguration of International Joint Ventures,” [Journal of International Business Studies] Vol.29 P.773-796 google cross ref
  • 41. Wernerfelt B. (1985) “A Resource-Based View of the Firm,” [Strategic Management Journal] Vol.5 P.171-180 google
OAK XML 통계
이미지 / 테이블
  • [ Figure 1 ]  Research Model
    Research Model
  • [ Table 1 ]  Maximum Likelihood Factor Analysis: Varimax Rotation
    Maximum Likelihood Factor Analysis: Varimax Rotation
  • [ Table 2 ]  Measurement Model
    Measurement Model
  • [ Table 3 ]  Discriminant Validity
    Discriminant Validity
  • [ Table 4 ]  Summary of the Path Estimates (N=51)
    Summary of the Path Estimates (N=51)
(우)06579 서울시 서초구 반포대로 201(반포동)
Tel. 02-537-6389 | Fax. 02-590-0571 | 문의 : oak2014@korea.kr
Copyright(c) National Library of Korea. All rights reserved.